Re: fixing the banks and the economy


[Skip to the end]

(email exchange)

Comes down to the fundamentals of banking and public purpose.

Presumably it serves public purpose for banks to have private equity capital as a ‘first loss’ piece to ‘protect’ government from loss due to deposit insurance.

Either it does or it doesn’t suit public purpose to do that at any give point in time.

‘Injecting’ government capital to act as a first loss piece to protect government from loss due to deposit insurance is nonsensical as government is in a first loss position either way.

Nationalizing means government is in a first loss position all the time.

So functionally, if a bank is insolvent due to insufficient (private) capital, and the government wants it to continue as a going concern, all it has to do is continue to insure the liabilities as it currently does, and permit the institution to continue operations desired by government without sufficient private capital ratios.

Government can also set a ‘cost’ for doing this if it’s concerned about private shareholders and uninsured creditors ‘profiting’ for these measures.

Etc.

But at the macro level banking is not viable without government doing job one of sustaining aggregate demand via getting the fiscal balance right. Or at least sufficient to muddle through.

Lending makes no economic sense to a for profit institution with falling asset prices and falling incomes.

So a full payroll tax holiday and a $300 billion no strings attached transfer to the states restores aggregate demand and stabilizes asset prices.

Delinquencies fall and the ‘toxic waste’ turns AAA, as everyone wonders what all the fuss was all about.

And a national service job for anyone willing and able to work that includes health care elevates life to a new level of prosperity which should have been considered normal all along.

>   
>   On Fri, Jan 23, 2009 at 11:39 PM, Russell wrote:
>   
>   George Soros, in a comment in today’s Financial Times, “The right and wrong
>   way to bail out the banks,” takes issue with the idea of reviving TARP 1.0 in
>   new dress and suggests another approach for dealing with the banking crisis:
>   
>   According to reports in Washington, the Obama administration may be close to
>   devoting as much as $100bn of the second tranche of the troubled asset relief
>   programme funds to creating an “aggregator bank” that would remove toxic
>   securities from the balance sheets of banks. The plan would be to leverage
>   this amount up 10-fold, using the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet, so that
>   the banking system could be relieved of up to $1,000bn (€770bn, £726bn)
>   worth of bad assets…..
>   
>   [T]his approach harks back to the approach originally taken – but eventually
>   abandoned – by Hank Paulson, the former US Treasury secretary. The
>   proposal suffers from the same shortcomings: the toxic securities are, by
>   definition, hard to value. The introduction of a significant buyer will result, not
>   in price discovery, but in price distortion.
>   
>   Moreover, the securities are not homogeneous, which means that even an
>   auction process would leave the aggregator bank with inferior assets through
>   adverse selection…..
>   
>   These measures – if enacted – would provide artificial life support for the
>   banks at considerable expense to the taxpayer, but would not put the banks
>   in a position to resume lending at competitive rates….
>   
>   In my view, an equity injection scheme based on realistic valuations, followed
>   by a cut in minimum capital requirements for banks, would be much more
>   effective in restarting the economy. The downside is that it would require
>   significantly more than $1,000bn of new capital. It would involve a good
>   bank/bad bank solution, where appropriate. That would heavily dilute existing
>   shareholders and risk putting the majority of bank equity into government
>   hands.
>   


[top]

WSJ- The World Won’t Buy Unlimited US Debt


[Skip to the end]

The World Won’t Buy Unlimited US Debt

by Peter Schiff

Jan 23 (Wall Street Journal) — Barack Obama has spoken often of sacrifice. And as recently as a week ago, he said that to stave off the deepening recession Americans should be prepared to face “trillion dollar deficits for years to come.”
But apart from a stirring call for volunteerism in his inaugural address, the only specific sacrifices the president has outlined thus far include lower taxes, millions of federally funded jobs, expanded corporate bailouts, and direct stimulus checks to consumers. Could this be described as sacrificial?

No. Good point! Why should utilizing idle resources be sacrificial?

It’s only during times of scarcity does ‘sacrifice’ come into play.

What he might have said was that the nations funding the majority of America’s public debt — most notably the Chinese, Japanese and the Saudis — need to be prepared to sacrifice.

They already have been and want to continue net exporting to the US.

That is true sacrifice, and they are begging to be allowed to continue doing it.

They have to fund America’s annual trillion-dollar deficits for the foreseeable future.

No, we have funded their savings.

These creditor nations, who already own trillions of dollars of U.S. government debt, are the only entities capable of underwriting the spending that Mr. Obama envisions and that U.S. citizens demand.

No, they push to get to the front of the line to accumulate USD financial assets as part of their desire to net export (sacrifice) to the US.

These nations, in other words, must never use the money to buy other assets or fund domestic spending initiatives for their own people.

Yes, it’s better for us if they don’t. But they can at any time. And lucky for us they don’t want to.

When the old Treasury bills mature, they can do nothing with the money except buy new ones. To do otherwise would implode the market for U.S. Treasurys (sending U.S. interest rates much higher)

Maybe.

and start a run on the dollar. (If foreign central banks become net sellers of Treasurys, the demand for dollars needed to buy them would plummet.)

Only if they sell USD for other currencies, or spend those USD here.

And if the dollar goes down, so what? While it’s not my first choice to enact policy that causes the dollar to go down for other reasons, it does not alter the real wealth of the US.

Real wealth= everything produced domestically plus everything imported minus everything exported.

Exports are always a cost, imports a benefit.

In sum, our creditors must give up all hope of accessing the principal, and may be compensated only by the paltry 2%-3% yield our bonds currently deliver.

And if they never spend the USD interest earned is of no real consequence either.

As absurd as this may appear on the surface, it seems inconceivable to President Obama, or any respected economist for that matter, that our creditors may decline to sign on.

You would think they would have realized net exports hurt them long ago. But as of today they are still clawing and biting to increase net exports.

And, worse yet, our fearless leaders are trying to reverse that and balance of trade account.

Their confidence is derived from the fact that the arrangement has gone on for some time, and that our creditors would be unwilling to face the economic turbulence that would result from an interruption of the status quo.

No, they do it to support their export industries that have disproportionate political clout, supported by international mainstream economics that praises exports and condemns imports.

But just because the game has lasted thus far does not mean that they will continue playing it indefinitely.

Agreed! But we should strive to continue it, not strive to end it.

Thanks to projected huge deficits, the U.S. government is severely raising the stakes. At the same time, the global economic contraction will make larger Treasury purchases by foreign central banks both economically and politically more difficult.

No, it makes it more urgent, as they have no instinct to increase their domestic demand, but instead focus on supporting their exports.

The root problem is not that America may have difficulty borrowing enough from abroad to maintain our GDP, but that our economy was too large in the first place. America’s GDP is composed of more than 70% consumer spending.

Pretty normal. The entire point of any economy is consumption. The rest is investment which represents a down payment on future consumption.

For many years, much of that spending has been a function of voracious consumer borrowing through home equity extractions (averaging more than $850 billion annually in 2005 and 2006, according to the Federal Reserve) and rapid expansion of credit card and other consumer debt. Now that credit is scarce, it is inevitable that GDP will fall.

Yes, but because government doesn’t understand its role in sustaining domestic demand.

Neither the left nor the right of the American political spectrum has shown any willingness to tolerate such a contraction. Recently, for example, Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Krugman estimated that a 6.8% contraction in GDP will result in $2.1 trillion in “lost output,” which the government should redeem through fiscal stimulation. In his view, the $775 billion announced in Mr. Obama’s plan is two-thirds too small.

Agreed!

Although Mr. Krugman may not get all that he wishes, it is clear that Mr. Obama’s opening bid will likely move north considerably before any legislation is passed. It is also clear from the political chatter that the policies most favored will be those that encourage rapid consumer spending, not lasting or sustainable economic change. So when the effects of this stimulus dissipate, the same unbalanced economy will remain — only now with a far higher debt load.

There is no reason for fiscal balance to ‘dissipate’ but instead can be continually altered to support aggregate demand/output/employment.

Currently, U.S. citizens comprise less than 5% of world population, but account for more than 25% of global GDP. Given our debts and weakening economy, this disproportionate advantage should narrow. Yet the U.S. is asking much poorer foreign nations to maintain the status quo, and incredibly, they are complying. At least for now.

We aren’t asking them to export to us, they are demanding the right to export to us.

You can’t blame the Obama administration for choosing to go down this path. If these other nations are giving, it becomes very easy to take.

In fact, foolish not to.

However, given his supposedly post-ideological pragmatic gifts, one would hope that Mr. Obama can see that, just like all other bubbles in world history, the U.S. debt bubble will end badly. Taking on more debt to maintain spending is neither sacrificial nor beneficial.

He misses the point. There is no financial risk to government ‘debt’, only the risk of inflation.

Government continuously has the option to sustain domestic demand and no reason not to do so apart from deficit myths and a lack of understanding of our monetary system.

Mr. Schiff is president of Euro Pacific Capital and author of “The Little Book of Bull Moves in Bear Markets” (Wiley, 2008).


[top]

Korea using Fed swap lines (cont.)


[Skip to the end]

Got some new players as well!

Bank of Korea to Supply $3 Billion to Local Banks

Jan 19 (Korea Times) — South Korea’s central bank said Monday it will provide $3 billion to local banks suffering from a dollar liquidity crunch in the wake of the U.S.-sparked global financial turmoil, Yonhap News reported Monday.

The Bank of Korea (BOK) said the money is part of a $30 billion currency swap agreement it signed with the U.S. Federal Reserve in late October. The BOK has tapped $13.35 billion out of the swap line so far.

The central bank plans to hold an auction Tuesday and the loans will mature in 84 days.

The move comes amid rising market jitters about South Korea’s falling foreign exchange reserves, the world’s sixth-largest.

The country’s foreign reserves, which totaled $201.22 billion as of the end of December, fell for eight consecutive months in 2008, before climbing slightly in December as a weaker U.S. dollar boosted the dollar value of assets in other currencies.

South Korea also reached new currency swap arrangements with China and Japan in late December, expanding its existing swap lines with the two countries to $30 billion each.


[top]

Bernanke speech


[Skip to the end]

Chairman Ben S. Bernanke- At the Stamp Lecture, London School of Economics, London, England

Jan 13, 2009

The Crisis and Policy Response

(Some text omitted)

Heightened systemic risks, falling asset values, and tightening credit have in turn taken a heavy toll on business and consumer confidence and precipitated a sharp slowing in global economic activity. The damage, in terms of lost output, lost jobs, and lost wealth, is already substantial.

Yes, they have reduced aggregate demand. The question is what the Fed can do, if anything, to restore demand?

The global economy will recover, but the timing and strength of the recovery are highly uncertain.

Yes, after the federal budget deficit gets large enough to restore aggregate demand.

The Federal Reserve’s Response to the Crisis

The Federal Reserve has responded aggressively to the crisis since its emergence in the summer of 2007. Following a cut in the discount rate (the rate at which the Federal Reserve lends to depository institutions) in August of that year, the Federal Open Market Committee began to ease monetary policy in September 2007, reducing the target for the federal funds rate by 50 basis points.1 As indications of economic weakness proliferated, the Committee continued to respond, bringing down its target for the federal funds rate by a cumulative 325 basis points by the spring of 2008.

Maybe some day the underlying assumption that lower rates adds to aggregate demand will fall by the wayside.

The ‘math’ shows lower rates takes more income from savers than it adds to borrowers, as government is a net payer of interest.

The different propensities to consume between borrower and savers would have to be far wider than ever measured by econometrics to result in lower rates adding to demand.

In other words, there’s a good chance lower rates have made things worse.

In historical comparison, this policy response stands out as exceptionally rapid and proactive. In taking these actions, we aimed both to cushion the direct effects of the financial turbulence on the economy and to reduce the virulence of the so-called adverse feedback loop, in which economic weakness and financial stress become mutually reinforcing.

Lower rates have failed to do this. Maybe their ‘interest rate theory’ is backwards, as all evidence and logic shows???

These policy actions helped to support employment and incomes during the first year of the crisis.

No, incomes suffered from lower interest income. Employment was sustained from what was a temporary boom in exports and government spending.

Unfortunately, the intensification of the financial turbulence last fall led to further deterioration in the economic outlook. The Committee responded by cutting the target for the federal funds rate an additional 100 basis points last October, with half of that reduction coming as part of an unprecedented coordinated interest rate cut by six major central banks on October 8. In December the Committee reduced its target further, setting a range of 0 to 25 basis points for the target federal funds rate.

And all their economies got worse.

The Committee’s aggressive monetary easing was not without risks.

The largest risk was that Congress would believe they might help and not implement large enough fiscal measures, which is exactly what happened.

During the early phase of rate reductions, some observers expressed concern that these policy actions would stoke inflation. These concerns intensified as inflation reached high levels in mid-2008, mostly reflecting a surge in the prices of oil and other commodities.

As costs of production, lower interest rate reduce costs of national output.

The Committee takes its responsibility to ensure price stability extremely seriously, and throughout this period it remained closely attuned to developments in inflation and inflation expectations. However, the Committee also maintained the view that the rapid rise in commodity prices in 2008 primarily reflected sharply increased demand for raw materials in emerging market economies,

And pension funds and trend followers- don’t they know about that?

in combination with constraints on the supply of these materials, rather than general inflationary pressures. Committee members expected that, at some point, global economic growth would moderate, resulting in slower increases in the demand for commodities and a leveling out in their prices–as reflected, for example, in the pattern of futures market prices. As you know, commodity prices peaked during the summer and, rather than leveling out, have actually fallen dramatically with the weakening in global economic activity. As a consequence, overall inflation has already declined significantly and appears likely to moderate further.

No talk of the Great Mike Masters Futures Led Inventory Liquidation triggered in July.

It had nothing to do with monetary policy or the economy.

The Fed’s monetary easing has been reflected in significant declines in a number of lending rates, especially shorter-term rates, thus offsetting to some degree the effects of the financial turmoil on financial conditions.

They do control interest rates, whether they know it or not, and whether they know what buttons to push or not.

However, that offset has been incomplete, as widening credit spreads, more restrictive lending standards, and credit market dysfunction have worked against the monetary easing and led to tighter financial conditions overall. In particular, many traditional funding sources for financial institutions and markets have dried up, and banks and other lenders have found their ability to securitize mortgages, auto loans, credit card receivables, student loans, and other forms of credit greatly curtailed. Thus, in addition to easing monetary policy, the Federal Reserve has worked to support the functioning of credit markets and to reduce financial strains by providing liquidity to the private sector. In doing so, as I will discuss shortly, the Fed has deployed a number of additional policy tools, some of which were previously in our toolkit and some of which have been created as the need arose.

Beyond the Federal Funds Rate: The Fed’s Policy Toolkit

Although the federal funds rate is now close to zero, the Federal Reserve retains a number of policy tools that can be deployed against the crisis.

One important tool is policy communication. Even if the overnight rate is close to zero, the Committee should be able to influence longer-term interest rates by informing the public’s expectations about the future course of monetary policy.

It can also directly set risk-free long term rates by intervening in the treasury markets and/or swap markets, targeting rates and letting quantity fall where it may.

To illustrate, in its statement after its December meeting, the Committee expressed the view that economic conditions are likely to warrant an unusually low federal funds rate for some time.2 To the extent that such statements cause the public to lengthen the horizon over which they expect short-term rates to be held at very low levels, they will exert downward pressure on longer-term rates,

Why not just have a bid for long term rates at their target rate of choice?

stimulating aggregate demand.

This assumes aggregate demand is a function of rates, and in the direction they think it is. I would argue they are most likely backwards in that respect.

It is important, however, that statements of this sort be expressed in conditional fashion–that is, that they link policy expectations to the evolving economic outlook. If the public were to perceive a statement about future policy to be unconditional, then long-term rates might fail to respond in the desired fashion should the economic outlook change materially.

Other than policies tied to current and expected future values of the overnight interest rate, the Federal Reserve has–and indeed, has been actively using–a range of policy tools to provide direct support to credit markets and thus to the broader economy. As I will elaborate, I find it useful to divide these tools into three groups. Although these sets of tools differ in important respects, they have one aspect in common: They all make use of the asset side of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. That is, each involves the Fed’s authorities to extend credit or purchase securities.

The first set of tools, which are closely tied to the central bank’s traditional role as the lender of last resort, involve the provision of short-term liquidity to sound financial institutions. Over the course of the crisis, the Fed has taken a number of extraordinary actions to ensure that financial institutions have adequate access to short-term credit.

They are actually reversing extraordinary actions taken in the past to obstruct bank access to short term credit.

In particular demanding collateral from member banks when the Fed lends to them. This is both redundant (FDIC already insures bank deposits and regulates assets, etc.) and obstructive.

These actions include creating new facilities for auctioning credit and making primary securities dealers, as well as banks, eligible to borrow at the Fed’s discount window.3 For example, since August 2007 we have lowered the spread between the discount rate and the federal funds rate target from 100 basis points to 25 basis points;

Why is it above the Fed funds rate and not the same rate? The idea of a ‘penalty rate’ is a result of a lack of understanding of monetary operations with a non-convertible currency.

increased the term of discount window loans from overnight to 90 days;

Yes, this hints at what I was saying before- they can set the entire term structure of rates at will.

created the Term Auction Facility, which auctions credit to depository institutions for terms up to three months;

But sets a quantity and lets an auction process determine the rate. This is backwards. They should always set a rate and let the quantity fall where it may.

put into place the Term Securities Lending Facility, which allows primary dealers to borrow Treasury securities from the Fed against less-liquid collateral;

This is better done by having the Fed lend against that collateral directly. Not sure why they do it this way.

and initiated the Primary Dealer Credit Facility as a source of liquidity for those firms, among other actions.

That should have been done via their designated agents, the banks, via qualified guarantees.

Because interbank markets are global in scope, the Federal Reserve has also approved bilateral currency swap agreements with 14 foreign central banks. The swap facilities have allowed these central banks to acquire dollars from the Federal Reserve to lend to banks in their jurisdictions, which has served to ease conditions in dollar funding markets globally. In most cases, the provision of this dollar liquidity abroad was conducted in tight coordination with the Federal Reserve’s own funding auctions.

Yes, this was an act of madness- functionally unsecured loans of over $600 billion to foreign CBs.

Congress has no idea what’s going on, and I suspect they would put quick halt to this if they had any understanding of it.

There are far less risky alternatives to bringing LIBOR down to the Fed’s targets for it..

Importantly, the provision of credit to financial institutions exposes the Federal Reserve to only minimal credit risk; the loans that we make to banks and primary dealers through our various facilities are generally overcollateralized and made with recourse to the borrowing firm.The Federal Reserve has never suffered any losses in the course of its normal lending to banks and, now, to primary dealers. In the case of currency swaps, the foreign central banks are responsible for repayment, not the financial institutions that ultimately receive the funds; moreover, as further security, the Federal Reserve receives an equivalent amount of foreign currency in exchange for the dollars it provides to foreign central banks.

This is no different than the Fed buying foreign ‘dollar bonds’ from the foreign governments, which have repeatedly gone bad in the past.

Is he really thinking foreign governments ‘automatically’ are good credit risks?

The line to Mexico is $30 billion, for example, and the ECB line is actually stated to be ‘unlimited’.

The currency the Fed ‘receives’ is nothing more than a deposit on the foreign central banks own books.

And the outstanding total is over $600 billion!

How does he miss all this???

Liquidity provision by the central bank reduces systemic risk by assuring market participants that, should short-term investors begin to lose confidence, financial institutions will be able to meet the resulting demands for cash without resorting to potentially destabilizing fire sales of assets.

True. It should have been set up years ago to make sure the liability side of banking is not the place of market discipline.

Moreover, backstopping the liquidity needs of financial institutions reduces funding stresses and, all else equal, should increase the willingness of those institutions to lend and make markets.

On the other hand, the provision of ample liquidity to banks and primary dealers is no panacea. Today, concerns about capital, asset quality, and credit risk continue to limit the willingness of many intermediaries to extend credit, even when liquidity is ample. Moreover, providing liquidity to financial institutions does not address directly instability or declining credit availability in critical nonbank markets, such as the commercial paper market or the market for asset-backed securities, both of which normally play major roles in the extension of credit in the United States.

Lending is pro-cyclical, get over it! Only government can be counter cyclical with fiscal policy.

To address these issues, the Federal Reserve has developed a second set of policy tools, which involve the provision of liquidity directly to borrowers and investors in key credit markets.

Actually addresses interest rates.

Notably, we have introduced facilities to purchase highly rated commercial paper

Are these the same guys that were critical of investors relying on ratings agencies???

at a term of three months and to provide backup liquidity for money market mutual funds. In addition, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury have jointly announced a facility that will lend against AAA-rated asset-backed securities collateralized by student loans, auto loans, credit card loans, and loans guaranteed by the Small Business Administration. The Federal Reserve’s credit risk exposure in the latter facility will be minimal, because the collateral will be subject to a “haircut” and the Treasury is providing $20 billion of capital as supplementary loss protection. We expect this facility to be operational next month.

Interesting how he explains how the Fed is safe at least partially because it shifted risk to the treasury.

Seems they are both on the same team in the same game???

The rationales and objectives of our various facilities differ, according to the nature of the problem being addressed. In some cases, as in our programs to backstop money market mutual funds, the purpose of the facility is to serve, once again in classic central bank fashion, as liquidity provider of last resort. Following a prominent fund’s “breaking of the buck”–that is, a decline in its net asset value below par–in September, investors began to withdraw funds in large amounts from money market mutual funds that invest in private instruments such as commercial paper and certificates of deposit. Fund managers responded by liquidating assets and investing at only the shortest of maturities. As the pace of withdrawals increased, both the stability of the money market mutual fund industry and the functioning of the commercial paper market were threatened.

It was part of the ongoing process of shifting funding back to the banking system as risk was being re-priced.

The Federal Reserve responded with several programs, including a facility to finance bank purchases of high-quality asset-backed commercial paper from money market mutual funds. This facility effectively channeled liquidity to the funds, helping them to meet redemption demands without having to sell assets indiscriminately.

This obstructed the process of moving funding back to its own banking system. The assets were moving to spreads wide enough to be held in bank portfolios. The Fed could have facilitated that process rather than obstructing it.

Together with a Treasury program that provided partial insurance to investors in money market mutual funds, these efforts helped stanch the cash outflows from those funds

Outflows to the Fed’s member banks.

and stabilize the industry.

Which can only compete with banks with help from the Fed.

The Federal Reserve’s facility to buy high-quality (A1-P1) commercial paper

Again with the ratings agencies!

at a term of three months was likewise designed to provide a liquidity backstop, in this case for investors and borrowers in the commercial paper market. As I mentioned, the functioning of that market deteriorated significantly in September, with borrowers finding financing difficult to obtain, and then only at high rates and very short (usually overnight) maturities.

The Fed could have facilitated the transition back to the banking system with provisions for banks to obtain Fed funding for the assets moving in their direction. Again, they got it wrong.

By serving as a backup source of liquidity for borrowers, the Fed’s commercial paper facility was aimed at reducing investor and borrower concerns about “rollover risk,” the risk that a borrower could not raise new funds to repay maturing commercial paper. The reduction of rollover risk, in turn, should increase the willingness of private investors to lend, particularly for terms longer than overnight. These various actions appear to have improved the functioning of the commercial paper market, as rates and risk spreads have come down and the average maturities of issuance have increased.

Would have been more constructively accomplished via the banking system.

In contrast, our forthcoming asset-backed securities program, a joint effort with the Treasury, is not purely for liquidity provision. This facility will provide three-year term loans to investors against AAA-rated securities backed by recently originated consumer and small-business loans.

Again, part of the Fed’s position of rate setter, and again, could have been better done via its member banks.

Unlike our other lending programs, this facility combines Federal Reserve liquidity with capital provided by the Treasury, which allows it to accept some credit risk.

You’re on the same team, guys!

By providing a combination of capital and liquidity, this facility will effectively substitute public for private balance sheet capacity, in a period of sharp deleveraging and risk aversion in which such capacity appears very short.

The banking system is already public balance sheet as banks have unlimited access to a variety of federally insured liabilities.

Why not use the banks for the purpose they are designed for? They already have the infrastructure necessary to manage this.

Instead, the Fed hires private managers!!!

If the program works as planned, it should lead to lower rates and greater availability of consumer and small business credit. Over time, by increasing market liquidity and stimulating market activity, this facility should also help to revive private lending. Importantly, if the facility for asset-backed securities proves successful, its basic framework can be expanded to accommodate higher volumes or additional classes of securities as circumstances warrant.

Nothing the banks can’t do given the same guarantees from the Fed.

The Federal Reserve’s third set of policy tools for supporting the functioning of credit markets involves the purchase of longer-term securities for the Fed’s portfolio. For example, we recently announced plans to purchase up to $100 billion in government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) debt and up to $500 billion in GSE mortgage-backed securities over the next few quarters. Notably, mortgage rates dropped significantly on the announcement of this program and have fallen further since it went into operation.

Hopefully no surprise! Again, the Fed is rate setter for the entire term structure as desired.

Lower mortgage rates should support the housing sector. The Committee is also evaluating the possibility of purchasing longer-term Treasury securities.

It would be functionally identical for the treasury simply not to issue them, as proposed by the BOE’s Goodhart today.

In determining whether to proceed with such purchases, the Committee will focus on their potential to improve conditions in private credit markets, such as mortgage markets.

These three sets of policy tools–lending to financial institutions, providing liquidity directly to key credit markets, and buying longer-term securities–have the common feature that each represents a use of the asset side of the Fed’s balance sheet, that is, they all involve lending or the purchase of securities. The virtue of these policies in the current context is that they allow the Federal Reserve to continue to push down interest rates and ease credit conditions in a range of markets, despite the fact that the federal funds rate is close to its zero lower bound.

Yes! It’s about price (interest rates) and not quantity.

Credit Easing versus Quantitative Easing

The Federal Reserve’s approach to supporting credit markets is conceptually distinct from quantitative easing (QE), the policy approach used by the Bank of Japan from 2001 to 2006. Our approach–which could be described as “credit easing”–resembles quantitative easing in one respect: It involves an expansion of the central bank’s balance sheet. However, in a pure QE regime, the focus of policy is the quantity of bank reserves, which are liabilities of the central bank; the composition of loans and securities on the asset side of the central bank’s balance sheet is incidental. Indeed, although the Bank of Japan’s policy approach during the QE period was quite multifaceted, the overall stance of its policy was gauged primarily in terms of its target for bank reserves. In contrast, the Federal Reserve’s credit easing approach focuses on the mix of loans and securities that it holds and on how this composition of assets affects credit conditions for households and businesses. This difference does not reflect any doctrinal disagreement with the Japanese approach, but rather the differences in financial and economic conditions between the two episodes. In particular, credit spreads are much wider and credit markets more dysfunctional in the United States today than was the case during the Japanese experiment with quantitative easing. To stimulate aggregate demand in the current environment, the Federal Reserve must focus its policies on reducing those spreads and improving the functioning of private credit markets more generally.

Another similarity is that neither did much for credit demand.

Note that the Fed’s ‘expanded balance sheet’ means that over $2 trillion of financial assets have been shifted to the Fed in exchange for a like amount of excess reserves and treasury securities being held by the private, non-government sectors.

If the average coupon on the securities the Fed removed (purchased) from the private sector was maybe 2% (more for some securities, less for others) that means this Fed action has removed over $40 billion per year of income from the private sector. This means about that much aggregate demand was removed which can only be ‘replaced’ by private credit expansion.

Seems this policy might not have been all that well thought out.

While I support the lower interest rates, I also recognize they probably do not add to demand and instead require a fiscal adjustment to sustain demand.

The stimulative effect of the Federal Reserve’s credit easing policies depends sensitively on the particular mix of lending programs and securities purchases that it undertakes. When markets are illiquid and private arbitrage is impaired by balance sheet constraints and other factors, as at present, one dollar of longer-term securities purchases is unlikely to have the same impact on financial markets and the economy as a dollar of lending to banks, which has in turn a different effect than a dollar of lending to support the commercial paper market.

Most likely none of them change demand enough to even offset the loss of interest income to the private sector as above.

Because various types of lending have heterogeneous effects, the stance of Fed policy in the current regime–in contrast to a QE regime–is not easily summarized by a single number, such as the quantity of excess reserves or the size of the monetary base. In addition, the usage of Federal Reserve credit is determined in large part by borrower needs and thus will tend to increase when market conditions worsen and decline when market conditions improve. Setting a target for the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet, as in a QE regime, could thus have the perverse effect of forcing the Fed to tighten the terms and availability of its lending at times when market conditions were worsening, and vice versa.

Finally, the Fed setting ‘price’ rather than ‘quantity!’ too bad it hasn’t figured this out for the TAFF and other operations.

The lack of a simple summary measure or policy target poses an important communications challenge. To minimize market uncertainty and achieve the maximum effect of its policies, the Federal Reserve is committed to providing the public as much information as possible about the uses of its balance sheet, plans regarding future uses of its balance sheet, and the criteria on which the relevant decisions are based.

We’ve seen the max effect.

Exit Strategy

Some observers have expressed the concern that, by expanding its balance sheet, the Federal Reserve is effectively printing money,

Only by narrow definitions of ‘money’ as below. Net financial assets held outside of government are always unchanged by Fed operations.

an action that will ultimately be inflationary.

Another questionable theory. But the Fed is worried about inflation expectations, which is yet one more questionable theory.

The Fed’s lending activities have indeed resulted in a large increase in the excess reserves held by banks. Bank reserves, together with currency, make up the narrowest definition of money, the monetary base; as you would expect, this measure of money has risen significantly as the Fed’s balance sheet has expanded. However, banks are choosing to leave the great bulk of their excess reserves idle, in most cases on deposit with the Fed.

There is no other option for the banking system as a whole.

Consequently, the rates of growth of broader monetary aggregates, such as M1 and M2, have been much lower than that of the monetary base. At this point, with global economic activity weak and commodity prices at low levels, we see little risk of inflation in the near term; indeed, we expect inflation to continue to moderate.

Right, as long as commodities keep going down.

However, at some point, when credit markets and the economy have begun to recover, the Federal Reserve will have to unwind its various lending programs. To some extent, this unwinding will happen automatically, as improvements in credit markets should reduce the need to use Fed facilities. Indeed, where possible we have tried to set lending rates and margins at levels that are likely to be increasingly unattractive to borrowers as financial conditions normalize. In addition, some programs–those authorized under the Federal Reserve’s so-called 13(3) authority, which requires a finding that conditions in financial markets are “unusual and exigent”–will by law have to be eliminated once credit market conditions substantially normalize. However, as the unwinding of the Fed’s various programs effectively constitutes a tightening of policy, the principal factor determining the timing and pace of that process will be the Committee’s assessment of the condition of credit markets and the prospects for the economy.

As lending programs are scaled back, the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet will decline, implying a reduction in excess reserves and the monetary base. A significant shrinking of the balance sheet can be accomplished relatively quickly, as a substantial portion of the assets that the Federal Reserve holds–including loans to financial institutions, currency swaps, and purchases of commercial paper–are short-term in nature and can simply be allowed to run off as the various programs and facilities are scaled back or shut down.

It will be interesting to see how the currency swaps run off. In the past governments with that much in dollar loans have not paid them off.

As the size of the balance sheet and the quantity of excess reserves in the system decline, the Federal Reserve will be able to return to its traditional means of making monetary policy–namely, by setting a target for the federal funds rate.

Why would it not continue to set the term structure of rates??? (Though again, personally I’d leave a zero rate policy in place at all times)

Although a large portion of Federal Reserve assets are short-term in nature, we do hold or expect to hold significant quantities of longer-term assets, such as the mortgage-backed securities that we will buy over the next two quarters. Although longer-term securities can also be sold, of course, we would not anticipate disposing of more than a small portion of these assets in the near term, which will slow the rate at which our balance sheet can shrink. We are monitoring the maturity composition of our balance sheet closely and do not expect a significant problem in reducing our balance sheet to the extent necessary at the appropriate time.

Importantly, the management of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and the conduct of monetary policy in the future will be made easier by the recent congressional action to give the Fed the authority to pay interest on bank reserves. In principle, the interest rate the Fed pays on bank reserves should set a floor on the overnight interest rate, as banks should be unwilling to lend reserves at a rate lower than they can receive from the Fed. In practice, the federal funds rate has fallen somewhat below the interest rate on reserves in recent months, reflecting the very high volume of excess reserves, the inexperience of banks with the new regime, and other factors.

Yes, like a few institutions that still do not earn interest on reserves.

However, as excess reserves decline, financial conditions normalize, and banks adapt to the new regime, we expect the interest rate paid on reserves to become an effective instrument for controlling the federal funds rate.

Moreover, other tools are available or can be developed to improve control of the federal funds rate during the exit stage. For example, the Treasury could resume its recent practice of issuing supplementary financing bills and placing the funds with the Federal Reserve; the issuance of these bills effectively drains reserves from the banking system, improving monetary control. Longer-term assets can be financed through repurchase agreements and other methods, which also drain reserves from the system. In considering whether to create or expand its programs, the Federal Reserve will carefully weigh the implications for the exit strategy. And we will take all necessary actions to ensure that the unwinding of our programs is accomplished smoothly and in a timely way, consistent with meeting our obligation to foster full employment and price stability.

How about asking Congress for permission to trade Fed funds directly with member banks? Again, requiring collateral is redundant with FDIC insurance and regulation already in place. That way the Fed could simply bid and offer Fed funds at its target rate and the Fed funds rate would be perfectly stable, with little or no interbank trading required.

Stabilizing the Financial System

The Federal Reserve will do its part to promote economic recovery, but other policy measures will be needed as well. The incoming Administration and the Congress are currently discussing a substantial fiscal package that, if enacted, could provide a significant boost to economic activity. In my view, however, fiscal actions are unlikely to promote a lasting recovery unless they are accompanied by strong measures to further stabilize and strengthen the financial system. History demonstrates conclusively that a modern economy cannot grow if its financial system is not operating effectively.

I don’t agree. Ongoing attention to fiscal balance that sustains output and employment will do just that, with or without the financial sector ‘operating efficiently,’ whatever that means.

In the United States, a number of important steps have already been taken to promote financial stability, including the Treasury’s injection of about $250 billion of capital into banking organizations,

Doesn’t hurt but doesn’t address the real problem- banks need borrowers with sufficient income and income prospects to make their payments.

a substantial expansion of guarantees for bank liabilities by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,

Another half measure. They need to remove the cap on the size of FDIC insured deposits at the same time they remove the collateral requirement at the discount window, and drop the discount rate to their target rate.

and the Fed’s various liquidity programs. Those measures, together with analogous actions in many other countries, likely prevented a global financial meltdown in the fall that, had it occurred, would have left the global economy in far worse condition than it is in today.

It didn’t need to happen at all.

However, with the worsening of the economy’s growth prospects, continued credit losses and asset markdowns may maintain for a time the pressure on the capital and balance sheet capacities of financial institutions. Consequently, more capital injections and guarantees may become necessary to ensure stability and the normalization of credit markets. A continuing barrier to private investment in financial institutions is the large quantity of troubled, hard-to-value assets that remain on institutions’ balance sheets. The presence of these assets significantly increases uncertainty about the underlying value of these institutions and may inhibit both new private investment and new lending. Should the Treasury decide to supplement injections of capital by removing troubled assets from institutions’ balance sheets, as was initially proposed for the U.S. financial rescue plan, several approaches might be considered. Public purchases of troubled assets are one possibility.

And highly problematic. They only ‘help’ if prices are above ‘market value,’ which means a direct subsidy.

Another is to provide asset guarantees, under which the government would agree to absorb, presumably in exchange for warrants or some other form of compensation, part of the prospective losses on specified portfolios of troubled assets held by banks.

Government already stands to ‘absorb’ all the losses in excess of bank capital via deposit insurance.

Yet another approach would be to set up and capitalize so-called bad banks, which would purchase assets from financial institutions in exchange for cash and equity in the bad bank.

Same issue as public purchases, above.

These methods are similar from an economic perspective, though they would have somewhat different operational and accounting implications. In addition, efforts to reduce preventable foreclosures, among other benefits, could strengthen the housing market and reduce mortgage losses, thereby increasing financial stability.

Banks need for borrowers to have sufficient income to make their mortgage payments.

Nothing the Fed does address this.

Only a fiscal adjustment can add net financial assets and income to the non-government sectors.

The public in many countries is understandably concerned by the commitment of substantial government resources to aid the financial industry when other industries receive little or no assistance. This disparate treatment, unappealing as it is, appears unavoidable. Our economic system is critically dependent on the free flow of credit, and the consequences for the broader economy of financial instability are thus powerful and quickly felt. Indeed, the destructive effects of financial instability on jobs and growth are already evident worldwide. Responsible policymakers must therefore do what they can to communicate to their constituencies why financial stabilization is essential for economic recovery and is therefore in the broader public interest.

If government understood the role of fiscal policy in sustain aggregate demand and thereby output and employment, with or without the financial sector, this would be mostly moot.

Even as we strive to stabilize financial markets and institutions worldwide, however, we also owe the public near-term, concrete actions to limit the probability and severity of future crises. We need stronger supervisory and regulatory systems under which gaps and unnecessary duplication in coverage are eliminated, lines of supervisory authority and responsibility are clarified, and oversight powers are adequate to curb excessive leverage and risk-taking.

Helpful, but more helpful is to understand the role of fiscal policy.

In light of the multinational character of the largest financial firms and the globalization of financial markets more generally, regulatory oversight should be coordinated internationally to the greatest extent possible. We must continue our ongoing work to strengthen the financial infrastructure–for example, by encouraging the migration of trading in credit default swaps and other derivatives to central counterparties and exchanges.

Right, that will bring back home buyers in droves…

The supervisory authorities should develop the capacity for increased surveillance of the financial system as a whole, rather than focusing excessively on the condition of individual firms in isolation; and we should revisit capital regulations, accounting rules, and other aspects of the regulatory regime to ensure that they do not induce excessive procyclicality in the financial system and the economy. As we proceed with regulatory reform, however, we must take care not to take actions that forfeit the economic benefits of financial innovation and market discipline.

What benefits? In 1972 housing starts were 2.6 million with a population of 215 million, and all we had were a bunch of sleep savings and loan associations taking in deposits and making mortgages, with modestly paid bank officers playing golf at 3:30 every day (I was one of them in 1973-75). A couple of years ago we peaked at 2 million housing starts with over 300 million people and called it ‘gangbusters’ and an unsustainable ‘bubble.’ And let’s just leave it at ‘a much larger and more highly paid’ financial sector dominating housing.

That’s progress?

Particularly pressing is the need to address the problem of financial institutions that are deemed “too big to fail.” It is unacceptable that large firms that the government is now compelled to support to preserve financial stability were among the greatest risk-takers during the boom period. The existence of too-big-to-fail firms also violates the presumption of a level playing field among financial institutions.

Not true. The ‘institution’ might be too big to fail, but not the shareholders, which is what matters regarding risk taking.

In the future, financial firms of any type whose failure would pose a systemic risk must accept especially close regulatory scrutiny of their risk-taking. Also urgently needed in the United States is a new set of procedures for resolving failing nonbank institutions deemed systemically critical,

True!

analogous to the rules and powers that currently exist for resolving banks under the so-called systemic risk exception.

Conclusion

The world today faces both short-term and long-term challenges. In the near term, the highest priority is to promote a global economic recovery. The Federal Reserve retains powerful policy tools and will use them aggressively to help achieve this objective. Fiscal policy can stimulate economic activity, but a sustained recovery will also require a comprehensive plan to stabilize the financial system and restore normal flows of credit.

Despite the understandable focus on the near term, we do not have the luxury of postponing work on longer-term issues. High on the list, in light of recent events, are strengthening regulatory oversight and improving the capacity of both the private sector and regulators to detect and manage risk.

Finally, a clear lesson of the recent period is that the world is too interconnected for nations to go it alone in their economic, financial, and regulatory policies. International cooperation is thus essential if we are to address the crisis successfully and provide the basis for a healthy, sustained recovery.

No, any nation can independently sustain domestic demand, output, and employment with appropriate fiscal policy.


[top]

2009-01-09 EU News Highlights


[Skip to the end]

Highlights

Trichet Sees ‘Significant’ Economic Worsening, II Magazine Says
European Confidence Drops to Record Low; Unemployment Increases
German Exports Drop 10.6% as Recession Hurts Orders
German Ministry Seeks $136 Billion Fund to Ease Company Credit
German bond sale’s fate signals trouble ahead

‘Bond failures’ are not all that uncommon in the eurozone and more of a debt management issue at this point.

However a rising deficit due to falling revenues and rising transfer payments as GDP weakens could cause the ability to fund to deteriorate rapidly.

Bank failures that require national government funding don’t help either, and the eurozone seems long overdue for multiple major bank failures.

German Builders See 2% Drop in Revenue in 2009, HDB Group Says
Steinmeier Casts Doubt on German Deficit Limit, Rundschau Says
Sarkozy Says France to Provide More Capital to Banks
Spain December Jobless Claims Rise as Economy Enters Recession
European Two-Year Government Notes Decline, Reversing Gains

German bond sale’s fate signals trouble ahead

by David Oakley

A German sovereign bond auction failed on Wednesday as investors shunned one of the most liquid and safe assets in the world in a warning for governments seeking to raise record amounts of debt to stimulate slowing economies.

The fate of the first eurozone bond auction of 2009 signals trouble ahead as governments around the world hope to issue an estimated $3,000bn in debt this year, three times more than in 2008.

The 10-year bonds failed to attract enough bids to reach the €6bn the German government wanted. Bids of €5.24bn, a cover of only 87 per cent, amounted to the second worst auction on record in terms of demand.

Such developments were rare before the credit crisis. Before the seven German bond auctions that failed last year, the last German bond auction to fail was in July 2000 after the dotcom crash.

Analysts said the vast amount of supply is deterring investors and a growing number of countries, including those with deep and mature bond markets, such as Germany, the UK and Italy, are struggling to attract buyers.

The Netherlands has seen bond auctions fail, the UK and Italy have been forced to offer investors higher yields to meet their auction targets, while Spain and Belgium have cancelled offerings because of a lack of demand.

The German finance agency admitted that investor appetite for government debt had waned, although insisted the auction was “not a disappointment”.

Meyrick Chapman, a UBS fixed-income strategist, said when a German bond auction failed it “does suggest there may be trouble ahead for other governments wanting to raise money in the debt markets. Before the financial crisis, German bond auctions just did not fail.”


[top]

Re: NYtimes.com: Mortgage Re- Defaults Rising, No Sign of Slowing


[Skip to the end]

>   
>   On Mon, Dec 22, 2008 at 12:29 PM, Bill wrote:
>   
>   The dominant reason loan modifications fail IMMEDIATELY is
>   because the borrower’s financial condition is far worse than
>   your records indicate. The most likely reason that’s true is
>   that your loan officers instructed the borrower to lie on the
>   original loan application so that the loan would be approved
>   and the loan officer would get a bigger bonus. The next most
>   common explanation is that the borrower lied on his own
>   initiative.
>   
>   Best, Bill
>   

Agreed, the primary reason for the losses is the lenders were defrauded, often by their own employees.

My proposal was for the government to let homes go into foreclosure and then buy them from the lenders at the lower of appraisal or the mortgage balance, and then rent them at fair market rents to the previous owner, with a right of first refusal on a sale which would happen a year or more in the future.

Yes, it’s an admin nightmare, but far less so than the other proposals and programs I’ve seen, and avoids issues with existing mortgage holders.

It ‘keeps people in their homes’ while at the same time provides for an orderly recycling of the homes.

But it’s never going to happen.

Also, delinquencies on the existing subprime loans seems to have leveled off for a couple of months at just under 20%, last I checked.

Warren

Mortgage re-defaults rising with no sign of slowing

WASHINGTON (Reuters) – The rate of home mortgage borrowers defaulting after their loans are modified is rising and shows no signs of leveling off, U.S. banking regulators said on Monday.

The data showed that after six months, nearly 37 percent of mortgage loans modified in the first quarter were 60 or more days delinquent. After three months, 19 percent were 60 or more days delinquent or in the process of foreclosure.

“One very troubling point is that, whether measured using 30-day or 60-day delinquencies, re-default rates increased each month and showed no signs of leveling off after six months or even eight months,” John Dugan, head of the Office of theComptroller of the Currency, said in a statement.

The number of delinquencies rose across all loan categories, although subprime loans had the highest default rates. At the same time, nine out of 10 mortgages remain current, the joint report by OCC and the Office of Thrift Supervision said.

Some U.S. lawmakers and the head of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corp have called for a more aggressive effort by lenders to modify mortgage terms to help keep people in their homes.

The data, some of which was released in preliminary form earlier this month, were based on information collected from some of the biggest U.S. institutions, such as Bank of America, Citibank and JPMorgan Chase.


[top]

Re: Looks like Central Banks are losing it


[Skip to the end]

(email exchange)

In actual fact they’ve never had it to lose.

>   
>   On Mon, Dec 22, 2008 at 11:02 AM, Russell wrote:
>   

The New Doom-and-Gloomers

My, how times have changed.

A year ago, few policymakers, “strategists,” or economists, here or elsewhere, saw an economic downturn coming (even though the National Bureau of Economic Research now says that a U.S. recession actually began in December 2007).

Now, as the following Agence France-Presse report, “World Faces Total Financial Meltdown: Spain’s Bank Chief,” reveals, we have central bankers who sound like doom-and-gloomers (gearing up to write their own books, perhaps?).

The governor of the Bank of Spain on Sunday issued a bleak assessment of the economic crisis, warning that the world faces a “total” financial meltdown unseen since the Great Depression.

“The lack of confidence is total,” Miguel Angel Fernandez Ordonez said in an interview with Spain’s El Pais daily.

“The inter-bank (lending) market is not functioning and this is generating vicious cycles: consumers are not consuming, businessmen are not taking on workers, investors are not investing and the banks are not lending.

“There is an almost total paralysis from which no-one is escaping,” he said, adding that any recovery – pencilled in by optimists for the end of 2009 and the start of 2010 – could be delayed if confidence is not restored.

No, if the appropriate fiscal balance is not restored-

Might I suggest an immediate payroll tax holiday?

Immediate revenue sharing?

Offering a federally funded job to anyone willing and able to work?

Doesn’t get any simpler than that?

Where’s the ‘complex’ problem?

Yes, they are too far out of paradigm to or they never would have let it all go this far, and being willing to wait yet another month for a fiscal response.

Sadly, another case of innocent fraud.

Ordonez recognised that falling oil prices and lower taxes could kick-start a faster-than-anticipated recovery, but warned that a deepening cycle of falling consumer demand, rising unemployment and an ongoing lending squeeze cannot be ruled out.

“This is the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression” of 1929, he added.

Ordonez said the European Central Bank, of which he is a governing council member, will cut interest rates in January if inflation expectations go much below two per cent.

“If, among other variables, we observe that inflation expectations go much below two per cent, it’s logical that we will lower rates.”

As if any of that matters.

Regarding the dire situation in the United States, Ordonez said he backs the decision by the US Federal Reserve to cut interest rates almost to zero in the face of profound deflation fears.

The blind leading the blind.

Central banks are seeking to jumpstart movements on crucial interbank money markets that froze after the US market for high-risk, or subprime, mortgages collapsed in mid 2007, and locked tighter after the US investment bank Lehman Brothers declared bankruptcy in mid-September.

Interbank markets are a key link in the chain which provides credit to businesses and households.

The central bankers and mainstream economists in general are the ‘missing links’, anthropologically speaking.


[top]

Krugman on deficits


[Skip to the end]

Deficits and the Future

By Paul Krugman

Right now there’s intense debate about how aggressive the United States government should be in its attempts to turn the economy around. Many economists, myself included, are calling for a very large fiscal expansion to keep the economy from going into free fall.

Sounds good.

Others, however, worry about the burden that large budget deficits will place on future generations.

OK.

But the deficit worriers have it all wrong. Under current conditions, there’s no trade-off between what’s good in the short run and what’s good for the long run; strong fiscal expansion would actually enhance the economy’s long-run prospects.

No, under any conditions coincident with a shortage of aggregate demand.

The claim that budget deficits make the economy poorer in the long run is based on the belief that government borrowing “crowds out” private investment — that the government, by issuing lots of debt, drives up interest rates, which makes businesses unwilling to spend on new plant and equipment, and that this in turn reduces the economy’s long-run rate of growth. Under normal circumstances there’s a lot to this argument.

Not true. There is never anything to this argument.

But circumstances right now are anything but normal. Consider what would happen next year if the Obama administration gave in to the deficit hawks and scaled back its fiscal plans.

Would this lead to lower interest rates? It certainly wouldn’t lead to a reduction in short-term interest rates, which are more or less controlled by the Federal Reserve. The Fed is already keeping those rates as low as it can — virtually at zero — and won’t change that policy unless it sees signs that the economy is threatening to overheat. And that doesn’t seem like a realistic prospect any time soon.

What about longer-term rates? These rates, which are already at a half-century low, mainly reflect expected future short-term rates. Fiscal austerity could push them even lower — but only by creating expectations that the economy would remain deeply depressed for a long time, which would reduce, not increase, private investment.

Both true.

The idea that tight fiscal policy when the economy is depressed actually reduces private investment isn’t just a hypothetical argument: it’s exactly what happened in two important episodes in history.

The first took place in 1937, when Franklin Roosevelt mistakenly heeded the advice of his own era’s deficit worriers. He sharply reduced government spending, among other things cutting the Works Progress Administration in half, and also raised taxes. The result was a severe recession, and a steep fall in private investment.

Yes, taxes were raised to pay for the new social security program and kept off budget. After the immediate economic setback they changed the accounting and put social security taxes on budget where they remain today. The lesson of public accounting for the government was and is that it best serves public purpose when it’s on a ‘cash basis’.

The second episode took place 60 years later, in Japan. In 1996-97 the Japanese government tried to balance its budget, cutting spending and raising taxes. And again the recession that followed led to a steep fall in private investment.

Yes, they kept pushing consumption taxes that set them back.

Just to be clear, I’m not arguing that trying to reduce the budget deficit is always bad for private investment. You can make a reasonable case that Bill Clinton’s fiscal restraint in the 1990s helped fuel the great U.S. investment boom of that decade, which in turn helped cause a resurgence in productivity growth.

No you can’t. The deficits of the early 90’s recession fueled the subsequent expansion, and the resulting surplus killed it, and we are still feeling the effects of those surplus years today.

What made fiscal austerity such a bad idea both in Roosevelt’s America and in 1990s Japan.

And the US in the late 90s- he conveniently bypasses that one?

were special circumstances:

No, fiscal austerity necessarily reduces aggregate demand.

in both cases the government pulled back in the face of a liquidity trap, a situation in which the monetary authority had cut interest rates as far as it could, yet the economy was still operating far below capacity.

Yes, because monetary policy- changing interest rates- doesn’t actually work as theorized by the mainstream.

And note that in the last year interest for savers has come down about 4% while interest charges for borrowers are about unchanged, or, in many cases, higher, as the spreads widened as the Fed cut rates. And in any case the non government is a net saver/net receiver of interest payments to the tune of the government’s outstanding treasury securities. So the largest consequence of last year’s rate cuts has been a cut in private sector interest income.

And we’re in the same kind of trap today — which is why deficit worries are misplaced.

At least he gets to the right place, even if it is via faulty logic.

One more thing: Fiscal expansion will be even better for America’s future if a large part of the expansion takes the form of public investment — of building roads, repairing bridges and developing new technologies, all of which make the nation richer in the long run.

Yes.

Should the government have a permanent policy of running large budget deficits? Of course not.

Why not, if demand is chronically weak, which it has been for a long time.

Although public debt isn’t as bad a thing as many people believe —

True!

it’s basically money we owe to ourselves —

Wrong reason :(

in the long run the government, like private individuals, has to match its spending to its income.

Wrong. He misses the difference between issuers of non convertible currencies with uses of those currencies.

The funds for us to pay taxes to come from government spending (or government lending). So government is best thought of as spending first and then collecting taxes or borrowing.

And every dollar of cash in circulation has to be from government deficit spending- funds spent but not yet collected for payment of taxes.

Etc.

Rookie mistake for a Nobel Prize winner not to see the difference between issuer and user of anything.

But right now we have a fundamental shortfall in private spending: consumers are rediscovering the virtues of saving at the same moment that businesses, burned by past excesses and hamstrung by the troubles of the financial system, are cutting back on investment.

Yes!

That gap will eventually close,

Not without sufficient deficit spending.

but until it does, government spending must take up the slack. Otherwise, private investment, and the economy as a whole, will plunge even more.

Yes!

How about a payroll tax holiday where the treasury makes the FICA payments for employees and employers, along with maybe $300 billion to the states for operations and infrastructure projects?

he bottom line, then, is that people who think that fiscal expansion today is bad for future generations have got it exactly wrong. The best course of action, both for today’s workers and for their children, is to do whatever it takes to get this economy on the road to recovery.

And keep it there.

Doesn’t he know about the ongoing ‘demand leakages’ taught in the text books? Tax advantaged pension funds, IRAs. insurance, and other corp reserves, etc. That grow geometrically (most years)?

And that’s why the full employment deficit is something like 5% of GDP, etc?

(If anyone knows Professor Krugman feel free to email this to him, thanks)


[top]

The Great Roubini


[Skip to the end]

Yes, he’s been calling for an economic collapse, that began in July. But looks like yet another case of ‘better lucky than good’ as he here demonstrates a lack of understanding of monetary and fiscal policy.

Roubini: Policies will lead to “much higher real interest rates on public debt”

From Dr. Roubini: Desperate Measures by Desperate Policy Makers in Desperate Times: the Fed Moves to Radically Unorthodox Policies as Economy Is in Free Fall and Stag-Deflation Deepens

Stag-deflation? Whatever.

Another batch of worse than awful news greeted today Americans getting ready for the Thanksgiving holiday: free falling consumption spending, collapsing new homes sales,

They’ve been very low but relatively flat for a while, as actual inventories of new homes for sale fell to multiyear lows.

falling consumer confidence, very high initial claims for unemployment benefits,

Initial claims actually fell a bit, as did continuing claims. And personal income is still growing though at a modest 0.3%. For some reason he has turned to sensationalism. Must be the overdose of TV cameras.

collapsing orders for durable goods. It is hard to get any worse than this but the next few months will serve even worse macro news. At this rate of contraction as revealed by the latest data it would not be surprising if fourth quarter GDP were to fall at an annualized rate of 5-6%.

And Roubini concludes:

[T]he Fed, together with the Treasury, started to implement some of the “crazier” policy actions that we discussed last week: a) outright purchases of agency debt and MBS to the tune of a whopping $600 billion;

This is far from crazy. The treasury should have been funding the agencies from inception. The fact that the government is finally coming around to this after more than 30 years is a move towards sanity.

b) another $200 billion of loans to backstop the consumer and small business credit markets (credit cards, auto loans, student loans, small business loans);

OK, but he doesn’t point out that the securities must be rated AAA and appropriate ‘margining’ will be applied. That is very conservative banking by any measure. Not to mention the $20 billion first loss piece the treasury is putting up from its TARP funds. If any agent is ‘crazy’ in this case it’s the treasury, not the Fed.

c) an effective policy of aggressive quantitative easing as the balance sheet of the Fed – already grown from $800 billion to over $2 trillion – will be expanded further as most of the new bailout actions and new programs will be financed via injections of liquidity

When the Fed buys securities it credits member bank reserve accounts, which now pay interest. (Is that what he means by ‘financed via injections of liquidity?’ What’s the problem here?)

rather than issuance of public debt.

Interest bearing reserve accounts are functionally identical to one day treasury securities.

The Fed is buying financial assets and the sellers in exchange have interest bearing deposits.

What’s the problem?

This is all nothing more than convoluted rhetoric that has not been thought through.

Effectively the Fed Funds rate has been abandoned as a tool of monetary policy …

That makes no sense. The FOMC continues to set a target for the Fed funds rate which the NY Fed continues to be responsible for hitting. That’s Geitner’s main job- to keep the Fed funds rate at the FOMC’s target. The Fed funds rate obviously remains a tool of monetary policy.

the Fed is now relying on massive quantitative easing and direct purchases of private sector short term and long term debts to try to aggressively push down short term and long term market rates.

Yes, in addition to its Fed funds target, the Fed is also targeting longer term rates. In fact, the Fed has always had the option of targeting the entire term structure of rates.

But that is not how quantitative easing has been defined. It was defined in the context of Japan, where the BOJ bought JGP’s to sustain excess reserves in the banking system under the mistaken notion that increasing the quantity of reserves would somehow alter the real economy. It was about quantity, not price. And it did not work as they expected.

Desperate times and desperate economic news require desperate policy actions

Clever.

The Treasury will be issuing in the next two years about $2 trillion of additional debt

It may net spend that much, and issue that much debt along with that net spending.

These policies – however partially necessary – will eventually lead to much higher real interest rates on the public debt

Maybe, but interest rates go up because the Fed raises them or because the markets anticipate the Fed will raise them. It is mainly about anticipating the Fed, rather than funding pressures, particularly for short term securities.

and weaken the US dollar

Yes, deficit spending that does not have positive supply side effects does have a weakening effect on the dollar, but it may simply stop it from getting as strong as it may have, rather than actually push it down vs other currencies.

once this tsunami of implicit and explicit public liabilities and monetary debt

What is ‘monetary debt’ as distinguished from ‘public liabilities?

driven by rising twin fiscal and current account deficits will hit a world where the global supply of savings is shrinking – as most countries moves to fiscal deficits thus reducing global savings

Government deficits in their local currency increase the savings of the non government sectors by the same amount.

Government deficit = private sector savings (net financial assets) as per national income accounting.

– and foreign investors start to ponder the long term sustainability of the US domestic and external liabilities.

Start to ponder???

To continue to attract massive inflows of capital, the U.S. might have to start paying higher interest rates on the public debt.

Totally inapplicable with a non convertible currency and a floating exchange rate. The causation is domestic credit expansion funds foreign savings, not vice versa. Loans create deposits. He’s probably got that backwards as well.

This is one of the concerns that Volcker (previous post) expressed in early 2005.

Yes.


[top]

German budget squeeze, the noose tightens


[Skip to the end]

More likely to be higher than expected as the economy deteriorates and credit markets remain problematic.

German Budget Squeezed as Crisis Hurts Revenue, Forces Outlays

By Brian Parkin

German Chancellor Angela Merkel’s government faces revenue shortfalls this year and will have to expand net borrowing in 2009 as the worst economic recession in at least 12 years takes its toll on the budget. Lawmakers meeting in Berlin overnight authorized next year’s net federal borrowing to rise to 18.5 bln euros ($23 bln) from the 10.5 bln euros forecast mid-year, the first increase since Merkel came to office exactly three years ago. The Finance Ministry also said today that the government may raise less money than planned from asset sales this year. “This is very clearly to do with the global financial situation,” Carsten Schneider, budget spokesman for the Social Democrats, coalition partners to Merkel’s Christian Democratic Union, said at a press conference in Berlin. “We are in very difficult economic times.” The government has tried to stem debt growth as the budget expands to pay for emergency programs ranging from tax relief on new low-emission cars to bigger subsidies for energy efficient buildings. Some economists have said that net borrowing may increase further as the recession deepens. “All signs point to a hard economic year for Germany, and this plays out on the budget,” Stefan Bielmeier, an economist with Deutsche Bank AG in Frankfurt, said in a Nov. 19 interview. Even so, Germany “may be getting off relatively lightly if it can keep the deficit that low.”


[top]