Richard Koo: a personal view of the macroeconomy


[Skip to the end]

I agree, and the deficit of consequence isn’t that high as I think that figure includes the TARP funds
which were a form of regulatory forbearance and not spending.

Unfortunately, elsewhere he falls short in explaining why deficit spending doesn’t have the downside risks the mainstream attributes to it.

Send him a copy of the 7 deadly innocent frauds draft for comment? (attached)

Richard Koo: a personal view of the macroeconomy

US a mirror image of Japan 15 years ago

In the last two weeks, I made my annual fact-finding mission to
Washington and also spent time in Boston and San Francisco. What I
witnessed was very reminiscent of the situation in Japan 15 years ago:
people were latching on to isolated fragments of good economic news as
evidence of recovery while ignoring the steady deterioration in the real
economy.

In addition to meetings with officials from the Federal Reserve and the
White House, I had the opportunity to talk with various groups at the
Hill including two Congresspersons over lunch.

Although there have been signs of improvement in the real economy,
particularly in production, the problems in the jobs picture are
underscored by the unemployment rate’s rise into double digits.

And on a personal level, the San Francisco bank that my parents
patronized for many years was shut down by the FDIC last Friday. To
prevent panic, the bank opened for business as usual on Saturday under
the name of another lender. This event added a personal dimension to the
crisis for me.

Budget deficit concerns make new fiscal stimulus all but impossible

One issue of particular concern on this trip was that people seem to be
paying little attention to the economic impact of the Obama
administration’s fiscal stimulus and instead are focusing entirely on
the size of the resulting budget deficit.

With the government running a deficit equal to 10% of nominal GDP, more
people are looking at the continued weakness in the economy:
particularly in employment: and drawing the conclusion that the
administration’s policies are ineffective and should be discontinued as
soon as possible. This view is so strong that additional fiscal stimulus
is seen as being almost impossible to implement today.

This pattern mirrors events in Japan 15 years ago. The more the
government draws on fiscal stimulus to avert a crisis, the more
criticism it receives.

People are giving no thought to the economic consequences if the
government had not responded to the $10trn loss in national wealth (in
the form of housing and stock portfolios) with fiscal stimulus. Instead,
they focus entirely on the fact that the economy has yet to improve
despite $787bn in expenditures.

In Japan, fiscal spending succeeded in keeping GDP above bubble-peak
levels despite the loss of Y1,500trn in national wealth, or three years
of GDP, from real estate and stocks alone. But because disaster was
averted, people forgot they were in the midst of a crisis and rushed to
criticize the size of the resulting fiscal deficits.

Their criticism prevented the Japanese government from providing a
steady stream of stimulus. Instead, it was forced to adopt a stop-and-go
policy of intermittent stimulus: each time a spending package expired,
the economy would weaken, forcing the government to quickly implement
the next round of stimulus. That is the main reason why the recession
lasted 15 years. And the mood in Washington today is very similar.

R. Koo


[top]

Richard Koo on fiscal policy and interest rates


[Skip to the end]

Met Richard years ago. Seems he’s still confused on fiscal policy:

Bond issues to fund capital injections will not lead to higher interest rates

Right! The CB sets rates. Too bad he didn’t stop here rather than try to explain the process.

Japan’s second round of capital injections was four times the size of the first, and some question the ability of US capital markets to absorb such a large emission of government debt. However, the 1989 S&L crisis demonstrated that funds raised for the purpose of rescuing the financial sector will not lead to higher interest rates.

True!

This is because, unlike fiscal outlays for public works, money spent to rescue the financial system does not reduce the amount of investment funds available in the financial markets.

Huh???

Assume, for example, that the government issues $100 of Treasury bonds to recapitalize a troubled bank.

And then makes a payment to the bank.

The bank receiving the capital injection would credit its capital account by $100 and then invest that $100. In effect, there will be $100 in the market to be invested regardless of whether the government issues debt to rescue the bank.

The $100 gets credited to the banks account at the CB. The bank can leave it there or look for alternatives.

Purchases of alternatives in the private sector cause the banks $100 to be ‘wire transferred’ to another bank.

That means the bank’s account at the CB is reduced by $100 and another bank’s account at the CB is increased by $100.

Because the $100 represents capital, the bank’s investment should be liquid and easily convertible into cash. The asset that best fills this bill is government securities

Ok.

If the bank decides to buy government debt with the money, the government will have another $100 to fund a capital injection.

I assume he means new government debt as he started with the government issuing $100 of bonds and recapitalizing the bank.

Two rubs.

First:

The government would only issue additional bonds if it wanted to (deficit) spend additional funds.

And it if wanted to issue bonds and (deficit) spend new funds, it would do so whether this particular bank wanted to buy the bonds or not. That is, the bank wanting to buy bonds is not the enabling force for (deficit) spending.

Second:

The sale of the original $100 of bonds reduced total bank reserves by $100 and the payment of the $100 to the bank added $100 to total bank reserves. So the initial bond issue and the recapitalization left bank reserves offset each other leaving total bank reserves unchanged. Institutionally, issuing new bonds starts a new series of transactions, and, again, that particular bank is not the enabling force.

If, on the other hand, the government uses that $100 to build bridges or roads, that money will leave the capital markets and be spent on wages or construction materials, producing a corresponding decrease in the amount of investment funds available.

I don’t follow this distinction at all.

In this case, as before, the Treasury borrowing $100 reduces bank balances at the CB by $100, and the Treasury spending $100 as above adds $100 to bank balances at the CB, leaving total bank balances (reserves) unchanged.

In short, money spent on public works projects leads to higher interest rates because it does not find its way back to the capital markets.

Not the case, interest rates go to where the CB sets them, one way or another.


[top]