Bernanke written testimony

As you know, financial markets in the United States and in a number of other industrialized countries have been under considerable strain since late last summer. Heightened investor concerns about the credit quality of mortgages, especially subprime mortgages with adjustable interest rates, triggered the financial turmoil. However, other factors, including a broader retrenchment in the willingness of investors to bear risk, difficulties in valuing complex or illiquid financial products, uncertainties about the exposures of major financial institutions to credit losses, and concerns about the weaker outlook for the economy, have also roiled the financial markets in recent months.

As the concerns of investors increased, money center banks and other large financial institutions have come under significant pressure to take onto their own balance sheets the assets of some of the off-balance-sheet investment vehicles that they had sponsored. Bank balance sheets have swollen further as a consequence of the sharp reduction in investor willingness to buy securitized credits, which has forced banks to retain a substantially higher share of previously committed and new loans in their own portfolios. Banks have also reported large losses, reflecting marked declines in the market prices of mortgages and other assets that they hold. Recently, deterioration in the financial condition of some bond insurers has led some commercial and investment banks to take further markdowns and has added to strains in the financial markets.

This had been expected to cause banks to not be able to lend as before. So far that hasn’t happened. Funds are there for credit-worthy borrowers.

The banking system has been highly profitable in recent years and entered this episode with strong capital positions. Some institutions have responded to their recent losses by raising additional capital. Notwithstanding these positive factors, the unexpected losses and the increased pressure on their balance sheets have prompted banks to become protective of their liquidity and balance sheet capacity and, thus, to become less willing to provide funding to other market participants, including other banks. Banks have also become more restrictive in their lending to firms and households. For example, in the latest Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey conducted by the Federal Reserve, banks reported having further tightened their lending standards and terms for a broad range of loan types over the past three months. More-expensive and less-available credit seems likely to continue to be a source of restraint on economic growth.

Bernanke sees the above as stemming from the supply side – bank’s becoming ‘protective’ of their balance sheets and rationing credit.

I see it, at the macro level, as banks being prudent in trying to lend only to people who can pay it back at spreads that compensate them for perceived risks.

In part as the result of the developments in financial markets, the outlook for the economy has worsened in recent months, and the downside risks to growth have increased.

Not sure if this means things have gotten worse since the last meeting – probably not.

To date, the largest economic effects of the financial turmoil appear to have been on the housing market, which, as you know, has deteriorated significantly over the past two years or so. The virtual shutdown of the subprime mortgage market and a widening of spreads on jumbo mortgage loans have further reduced the demand for housing, while foreclosures are adding to the already-elevated inventory of unsold homes. Further cuts in homebuilding and in related activities are likely.

Not much spillover yet.

Conditions in the labor market have also softened. Payroll employment, after increasing about 95,000 per month on average in the fourth quarter, declined by an estimated 17,000 jobs in January.

He must know January is subject to revision in a couple of weeks.

Employment in the construction and manufacturing sectors has continued to fall, while the pace of job gains in the services industries has slowed. The softer labor market, together with factors including higher energy prices, lower equity prices, and declining home values, seem likely to weigh on consumer spending in the near term.

Forward looking only? Seems he doesn’t think the consumer has already cut back all that much.

On the other hand, growth in U.S. exports should continue to provide some offset to the softening in domestic demand, and the recently approved fiscal package should help to support household and business spending during the second half of this year and into the first part of next year.

This could mean the Fed forecasts are for stronger growth now that the fiscal bill has been signed.

On the inflation front, a key development over the past year has been the steep run-up in the price of oil. Last year, food prices also increased exceptionally rapidly by recent standards, and the foreign exchange value of the dollar weakened.

The three negative supply shocks.

All told, over the four quarters of 2007, the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) increased 3.4 percent, up from 1.9 percent during 2006. Excluding the prices of food and energy, PCE price inflation ran at a 2.1 percent rate in 2007, down a bit from 2006.

Doesn’t mention the recent acceleration of core PCE over the last several months.

To date, inflation expectations appear to have remained reasonably well anchored,

Only ‘reasonably’.

but any tendency of inflation expectations to become unmoored or for the Fed’s inflation-fighting credibility to be eroded could greatly complicate the task of sustaining price stability and reduce the central bank’s policy flexibility to counter shortfalls in growth in the future.

Indicating that if they do elevate, it’s too late. Most of the FOMC agrees with this.

Accordingly, in the months ahead we will be closely monitoring inflation expectations and the inflation situation more generally.

To address these developments, the Federal Reserve has moved in two main areas. To help relieve the pressures in the interbank markets, the Federal Reserve–among other actions–recently introduced a term auction facility (TAF), through which prespecified amounts of discount window credit can be auctioned to eligible borrowers, and we have been working closely and cooperatively with other central banks to address market strains that could hamper the achievement of our broader economic objectives.
In the area of monetary policy, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has moved aggressively, cutting its target for the federal funds rate by a total of 225 basis points since September, including 125 basis points during January alone. As the FOMC noted in its most recent post-meeting statement, the intent of these actions is to help promote moderate growth over time and to mitigate the risks to economic activity.

Promote moderate growth over time. With inflation where it is, they can’t promote robust growth or full-employment. They need a positive output gap to bring inflation down to their long-term objectives.

A critical task for the Federal Reserve over the course of this year will be to assess whether the stance of monetary policy is properly calibrated to foster our mandated objectives of maximum employment and price stability and, in particular, whether the policy actions taken thus far are having their intended effects.

Doesn’t sound like there’s another cut coming? The ‘stance’ is the real rate, and without inflation coming down, keeping the stance constant doesn’t mean cutting rates.

Monetary policy works with a lag. Therefore, our policy stance must be determined in light of the medium-term forecast for real activity and inflation, as well as the risks to that forecast.

As follows:

At present, my baseline outlook involves a period of sluggish growth,

It would have to get worse for a change in stance.

followed by a somewhat stronger pace of growth starting later this year as the effects of monetary and fiscal stimulus begin to be felt.

Somewhat stronger – can’t get too strong and close the output gap.

At the same time, overall consumer price inflation should moderate from its recent rates, and the public’s longer-term inflation expectations should remain reasonably well anchored.

Headline CPI expected to flatten, but doesn’t mention core, which is probably projected to rise as it catches up to headline.

Although the baseline outlook envisions an improving picture, it is important to recognize that downside risks to growth remain, including the possibilities that the housing market or the labor market may deteriorate to an extent beyond that currently anticipated, or that credit conditions may tighten substantially further. The FOMC will be carefully evaluating incoming information bearing on the economic outlook and will act in a timely manner as needed to support growth and to provide adequate insurance against downside risks.

Barring a major deterioration in the growth outlook from ‘sluggish’ by the next meeting seems rates may be on hold.


Bernanke preview

If inflation is now above Bernanke’s comfort zone, as per Yellen who has been more dovish than Bermanke, and above their long-term target of maybe 2%, it can only be brought down by maintaining an output gap greater than zero under the mainstream theory they all subscribe to.

Particularly with the negative supply shocks of food, crude, and import/export prices persisting. And with energy prices (headline CPI) now showing up in core prices, also as per Yellen, inflation expectations are showing signs of coming unglued.

And the fiscal package has likely increased the Fed’s growth forecasts (smaller output gap) for Q2, Q3, and Q4.

The Fed believes a zero output gap means about a 4.75% unemployment rate.

That means the Fed wants to keep the economy from deteriorating and unemployment from rising, but it also doesn’t want unemployment falling to 4.75% which would mean it would have to act (rate hikes) to get it back up to something over 5% to meet long-term inflation targets.

So while Bernanke can say he stands by to do everything necessary to avoid a financial collapse, he also can’t allow the output gap to go to zero.


♥

2008-02-14 JN Highlights

News Headlines:

Japan Economy Grows 3.7%, Twice as Fast as Expected
Oct-Dec GDP Grows Annual 3.7% On Brisk Domestic, External Demand
Consumer Sentiment Fell For 4th Straight Month In Jan
Dec Revised Industrial Output Rises 1.4%
MOF Tsuda: GDP Confirms Recovery Despite Some Weakness
GDP COMMENT: Consumer Confidence Key To Future Growth

Seems to have done just fine last quarter without consumer confidence.


♥

The full employment recession is spreading

Looks like the US full-employment recession is spreading:

UK jobless rate falls to 5.2 percent in latest quarter

The unemployment rate in the United Kingdom in the last quarter of 2007 fell to 5.2 percent, down from 5.4 percent in the previous quarter, the government said Wednesday.

Average earnings, including bonuses, rose 3.7 percent in the fourth quarter compared with a year earlier, the Office for National Statistics said.

Yes, unemployment is a lagging indicator, but the subprime housing collapse is well over a year old. And the 4.9% rate in the US is, even by Yellen’s standards, ‘very close’ to full-employment.


2008-02-13 US Economic Releases

2008-02-13 MBAVPRCH Index

MBAVPRCH Index

Doesn’t look too bad.

Mortgage bankers have reduced staff and are probably working overtime on refi’s which remain very high.


2008-02-13 Retail Sales

Retail Sales

Details of today’s report aside, the year over year chart looks like retail sales have been working their way modestly higher during the last year.


♥

Sweden hikes rates due to cost push inflation

This is the mainstream approach to negative supply shocks:

“Don’t let relative value stories turn into inflation stories.” (as the Fed used to say)

And, they say, if you wait for the economy to get strong bringing the higher rates of inflation down gets more than that much harder.

STOCKHOLM, Sweden – Sweden’s central bank on Wednesday made a surprise increase in its key interest rate by a quarter of a percentage point to 4.25 percent in a move to keep inflation in check.

The hike surprised many market watchers who had expected the Riksbank to either cut its benchmark repo rate or keep it unchanged at 4 percent.

“There were expectations on a reduction. It was a surprising increase,” Handelsbanken analyst Marcus Hallberg was quoted as saying by Swedish news agency TT.

The bank said it expects the interest rate to stay “roughly” at the same level for the rest of the year. But in Wednesday’s announcement, the bank warned that “there is still considerable uncertainty regarding the economic outlook and inflation prospects,” and cautioned that while it currently expects the repo rate to stay near the new level, “there is considerable uncertainty in this assessment.”

The bank’s further course would depend on how economic developments abroad affect Sweden’s economic activity and inflation, it said.

Although economic activity remains strong, the bank said it deemed inflation to be high, and the rate rise will help to bring inflation back toward the target of 2 percent “a couple of years ahead.”

Inflation, or consumer price index, has been rising steadily in recent years and is now at 3.5 percent.

The bank said that “gross domestic product growth will slow down over the year and the increase in employment will slacken. Resource utilization in the economy will nevertheless be higher than normal.”

Inflation has been pushed up mainly by higher food and energy prices as well as cost pressures.

The bank said the continued global market financial turmoil and the unrest in the U.S., has led to “great uncertainty” and that recent developments in the financial markets mean that “the risk of weaker growth in the world economy has increased.”

Davide Stroppa, an economist at Bayerische Hypo- und Vereinsbank AG, described the raise as a “shock” in a research note.

“As we see it, with today’s move, the Riksbank exploited the window opportunity to deliver a hike before it will be too late and the dilemma of risks of a slower (although still quite respectable) growth and higher inflation would be solved in favor of the former.”

Sweden’s repo rate was last raised in October, by a quarter of a percentage point to 4 percent.


Another Yellen speech

Prospects for the U.S. Economy in 2008

(intro remarks snipped)

Today I’d like to talk about developments in the economy and in monetary policy, two items that have definitely been making the news lately. On January 22, the Federal Open Market Committee cut its main policy rate—the federal funds rate—by three-quarters of a percentage point. Then, on January 30, at the scheduled meeting, the Committee voted to cut the policy rate again, this time by half a percentage point to 3 percent. Taking these actions together with those that began last September, the Committee has cut that rate by a total of 2¼ percentage points.

The purpose of these actions is to stimulate demand in the face of the combined impact of the severe contraction in housing and the related financial market disruptions.

The purpose has gone from restoring market functioning to stimulating demand.

While housing construction has been weak for more than two years, its effects did not spill over to most other sectors until fairly recently. That’s why we used to talk about a “dual economy,” with housing notably weak, but other sectors doing well. However, financial markets became disrupted in the middle of last year, which has not only intensified the housing slump, but also has tightened credit conditions for some households and businesses. The combined impact has led to slowing more broadly through the economy. It is this broader slowdown that has elicited Federal Reserve actions in recent months.

Now attention is turned to increasing demand to a fight a slowdown.

(SNIP)

Financial markets

I’d like to begin with a discussion of the disruptions in U.S. and global financial markets, because they influence not only the economy’s most likely course but also the risks that could alter that course. In my view, these disruptions are likely to continue for some time. In other words, I think they have laid bare some fundamental issues with the structure of the financial system that will require significant adjustments.

The financial disruptions are centered in the markets for asset-backed securities.

(SNIP DESCRIPTION OF ABS, RATINGS AGENCIES HISTORY, RISKS)

The bottom line is that, in recent years, the financial system has gone through a significant restructuring that made evaluating and pricing risk difficult. The reverberations of the resulting financial disruption are still with us. I’d like to describe some of them now.

However, the potential stimulatory effects of this drop in risk-free Treasury rates have been offset in many cases by another key feature of the financial turmoil, namely, a sharp rise in interest rate risk spreads, as riskier borrowers have had to pay higher premiums to compensate lenders for a perceived increase in the probability of default or losses in that event. On the corporate side, prime borrowers have actually experienced some net decline in interest rates since the shock first hit—that is, even though risk spreads are higher, they have been more than offset by lower Treasury rates. However, issuers of low-grade corporate bonds with greater credit risk, in contrast, face notably higher interest rates.

Risk has been repriced, and low grade borrowers are still paying more, even after Fed cuts.

The mortgage market has been the epicenter of the shock, and, not surprisingly, greater aversion to risk has been particularly apparent there, with spreads above Treasuries increasing for mortgages of all types. Although borrowing rates for low-risk conforming mortgages are now lower than they were before the financial shock hit, fixed rates on jumbo mortgages are higher on net. Subprime mortgages remain difficult to get at any rate. Moreover, many markets for securitized assets, especially non-agency mortgage-backed securities, continue to experience severe illiquidity; in other words, the markets are not functioning efficiently, or may not be functioning much at all.

She does not think markets are functioning efficiently.

The turmoil is reverberating in depository institutions as well.1 One problem is an unanticipated buildup of mortgages as well as LBO-related loans on their balance sheets.

(SNIP LBO DESCRIPTION)

Furthermore, as investors have pulled back from the markets for asset-backed securities, the value of these securities and CDOs has fallen dramatically, so banks and other financial institutions have had to write down their values, which has shrunk their capital and driven their stock prices down.


Another problem for bank balance sheets is that credit losses have been edging up.

The latest reverberation involves monoline financial guarantors.

(SNIP DESCRIPTION)

Fortunately, the banking system entered this difficult period in a strong position. Most institutions were extremely well capitalized. However, the combination of unanticipated growth in assets and in write-downs has put increased pressure on banks’ capital positions. Given their concerns about capital adequacy and their increased caution in managing liquidity, it is not surprising that they are tightening credit terms and restricting availability. At first, the focus was mostly on mortgages, but now it has spread to other kinds of loans, including home equity lines of credit, credit cards, and other consumer credit, as well as business loans. The tightening of credit is also a response to a now noticeable deterioration in credit quality, particularly for subprime mortgages; the losses in other parts of the consumer loan portfolio remain at relatively low levels from an historical perspective, but they, too, have edged up.

Worries here about the supply side of credit.

Finally, equity markets have hardly been immune to recent financial turbulence. Broad U.S. equity indices have been very volatile, and, on the whole, have declined since August, representing a restraint on spending. More recently, some of these declines have occurred as profits have come in below market expectations for some financial firms due to write-downs of the value of mortgage-backed securities.

My overall assessment is that the turbulence in financial markets is due to some fundamental problems that are not likely to be resolved quickly. The effects of these problems have now made credit conditions tighter throughout most of the economy’s private sector, and this will restrain spending going forward.

That is the actual risk – will spending be credit constrained going forward, and, if so, whether exports and/or government (deficit) spending will pick up the slack and support growth and employment.

The impact hit economic activity mainly in the fourth quarter, and so far, it has been starkly negative. After robust performance in the second and third quarters of last year, growth slowed significantly in the fourth quarter—to a pace of only ½ percent.

Subject to revision. They said much the same about Q3 until it was revised up sharply. And Q4 reported inventory draw-downs of 1.4%; so, demand wasn’t that bad. And it is not unusual for GDP to puring a relatively low number after a very strong quarter like Q3 of 4.9%

This brings me to the outlook for the economy.

Economic outlook

Current indicators point to continued anemic growth for at least the first half of this year as well as significant downside risks even to those weak expectations. As I mentioned at the outset, though the prolonged slump in housing construction did not spill over significantly to the rest of the economy during 2006 and much of 2007, when combined with the recent financial market turmoil, it has been central to the emergence of today’s slow-growth environment. And the course of its resolution will be a key factor in the economic outlook.

The main indicators are the payroll number and the ISM, which are both subject to revision/reversal in a few weeks, and the December trade numbers out later this week that may alter Q4 GDP forecasts.

Not to mention that the current environment has sufficient demand to generate inflation numbers above her comfort zone.

Forward-looking indicators of housing activity strongly suggest that the downward cycle may be with us a while longer.

Agreed, but may have bottomed and not be subtracting materially from GDP going forward.

Despite the subprime and jumbo mortgage challenges, home prices were largely stable in the Bay Area during the first three quarters of 2007. It remains to be seen, of course, how they will do as further market adjustments occur.

On the national level, housing construction probably will continue to contract through the end of this year.

That’s doubtful, but possible.

It is true that the residential construction sector is a fairly small piece of the overall economy and is unlikely to cause significant overall weakness in and of itself.

Right.

But the fallout from the housing cycle has many dimensions, and in the fourth quarter there were signs of spillovers to other sectors of the economy, most worrisomely, to consumer spending. This sector is a huge part of the economy—about 70 percent—and its growth slowed to a rate that is somewhat below its long-run trend in the face of spillovers from the housing market and rising energy and food prices.

A minor slowdown for one quarter, maybe, so far. And the question remains whether exports and government deficit spending will pick up the slack.

Looking ahead, developments related to housing are likely to continue to put a strain on consumers. For example, house prices have fallen noticeably and the declines have intensified. Moreover, futures markets for house prices indicate further—and even larger—declines in a number of metropolitan areas this year.

Future prices? Pretty think market to direct policy.

With house prices falling, homeowners’ total wealth is declining, and that could lead to a pullback in spending.

Maybe, but the Fed economists have no evidence of that.

At the same time, the fall in house prices may constrain consumer spending by lowering the value of mortgage equity; less equity reduces the quantity of funds available for credit-constrained consumers to borrow through home equity loans or to withdraw through refinancing.

Same, no evidence of that yet.

Indeed, it would not be surprising to see even more moderation over the next year or so, as consumers face additional constraints due to the declines in the stock market, the tightening of lending terms at depository institutions, and the lagged effects of previous increases in energy prices.

Spending is predominately a function of income, which has held up so far.

National surveys show that consumer confidence has plummeted. And I have been hearing comments and stories from my business contacts in the retail industry that are also downbeat. The rise in delinquency rates across the spectrum of consumer loans is strongly indicative of the growing strains on households.

Finally, another negative factor for consumption is that labor markets have softened. In recent months, growth in employment from a survey of business establishments slowed sharply, actually falling in January, and many other indicators point in the same direction. Slower job growth will have a negative impact on the disposable income available to households and therefore will provide an additional restraint on consumer spending.

If January is revised up, does the Fed change its tune? They said the same about December employment when it was reported as being low, and then a month later when it was revised to a decent positive number there was no comment. Same when August reported negative then revised to a respectable number a month later.

With the domestic consumer likely to be pretty hobbled, it is tempting to look at consumers beyond our own borders to be a source of strength for economic activity. Foreign real GDP has advanced robustly over the past three years. With the dollar falling well below its level of a year ago, U.S. exports have done very well; partly for this reason, U.S. net exports—exports minus imports—which consistently held growth down from 2000 to 2005, actually gave it a lift over the past couple of years. I expect net exports to remain a source of strength. But some countries—especially in Europe—are experiencing direct negative impacts from the ongoing turmoil in financial markets. Others are likely to suffer indirect impacts from any slowdown in the U.S. A slowdown here could well produce ripple effects lowering growth there through trade linkages, and recently this factor has been reinforced by a worldwide drop in stock prices.

Yes, exports could fall. But they are being driven by an attempt to exit $US financial assets and that means spending them here rather than accumulating them there.

The US has taken strong measures to keep foreigners from accumulating $US financial assets – calling CB’s currency manipulators if they add to their $US reserves, the Fed’s actions making it clear it doesn’t care about inflation, and geopolitical policy driving unfriendly oil producers from accumulating their savings in $US.

This could easily increase US exports and asset sales by $500 billion per year from current levels.

Economic policies are another important factor in gauging the economic outlook. As I have noted, the FOMC has eased the stance of monetary policy substantially in the past five months. Moreover, Congress has now passed a fiscal stimulus package to help the economy and it could provide notable stimulus in the latter half of this year.

Yes, good sized demand add there.

Even with such policy stimulus, the overall economy is still likely to turn in a very sluggish performance this year, expanding by a rate well below potential and creating more slack in labor markets. At 4.9 percent, the unemployment rate is already slightly above my estimate of its sustainable level.

Slightly? That confirms that even the most dovish Fed president thinks about 4.75% is the minimum non-inflationary unemployment rate.

Slow growth this year would most likely push unemployment even higher.

How high does it have to go to keep inflation from rising? To then bring it down to her comfort zone? She would have to say a lot, based on the apparent insensitivity of inflation to unemployment in recent years.

To sum it up, for the next few quarters, I see economic activity as weighed down by the housing slump and the negative factors now impacting consumer spending. It remains particularly vulnerable to the continuing turmoil in financial markets. My comments haven’t even touched on possible slowdowns in business investment in equipment and software and buildings. I see the growth risks as skewed to the downside for the near term.

Right, and agreed, demand has been weakening since Q2 2006 when the budget deficit became too small to support a strong enough credit expansion for full-employment. But exports picked up the slack when the subprime home buyers were the first to fall by the wayside.

In circumstances like these, we can’t rule out the possibility of getting into an adverse feedback loop—that is, the slowing economy weakens financial markets, which induces greater caution by lenders, households, and firms, and which feeds back to even more weakness in economic activity and more caution. Indeed, an important objective of Fed policy is to mitigate the possibility that such a negative feedback loop could develop and take hold.

The countercyclical tax structure limits this. Just like th early 1990s when the slowdown drove the budget deficit to 5% of GDP (equal to about a $750 billion deficit today) and added that much net financial equity to trigger and support the boom of the second half of the 1990s.

With a gold standard, this does not happen. The government run that kind of deficit without losing reserves and defaulting. Like the US did in 1934 when it went off the gold standard.

Now let me turn to inflation. The recent news has been disappointing. Over the past three months, the personal consumption expenditures price index excluding food and energy, or the core PCE price index—one of the key measures included in the FOMC’s quarterly forecasts—has increased by 2.7 percent, bringing the increase over the past twelve months to 2.2 percent. This rate is somewhat above what I consider to be price stability.

Yes, even as demand is slowing.

I expect core inflation to moderate over the next few years, edging down to around 1¾ percent under appropriate monetary policy.

What does that mean? She said the Fed has been cutting rates to add to demand. How does adding to demand bring down inflation?

Such an outcome is broadly consistent with my interpretation of the Fed’s price stability mandate. Moreover, I believe the risks on the upside and downside are roughly balanced. First, it appears that core inflation has been pushed up somewhat by the pass-through of higher energy and food prices and by the drop in the dollar. However, recently, energy prices have turned down in response to concerns that a slowdown in the U.S. will weaken economic growth around the world, and thereby lower the demand for energy.

Hardly! Oil is still trending higher, as it bounced off of $86 got through $94 yesterday. And January 2008 gasoline consumption was 1.4% over January 2007 – during the ‘slowdown’ emphasized above. Not to mention grain prices and the CRB in general. And anecdotal earnings reports showing trending cost push inflation taking hold both internationally and domestically.

Another factor that could restrain inflationary pressures is the slowdown in the U.S. economy.

Hasn’t yet. In fact, seems to be getting worse if anything.

This can be expected to create more slack in labor and goods markets, a development that typically has been associated with reduced inflation in the past.

Not in the 1970s. Not with ‘imported’ cost push inflation, and now with biofuels liking food to fuel and with a couple of billion up-and-coming consumers in India and China competing for resources.

And not to mention our own pension funds increasing their allocations to passive commodity strategies – pure, inflationary hoarding.

A key factor for inflation going forward is inflation expectations. These appear to have become well-anchored over the past decade or so as the Fed’s inflation resolve has gained credibility. Very recently, far-dated inflation compensation—a measure derived from various Treasury yields—has risen, but it’s not clear whether this rise is due to higher inflation expectations or to changes in the liquidity of those Treasury instruments or inflation risk. Going forward, we will need to monitor inflation expectations carefully to ensure that they do indeed remain well anchored.

Right, as if monitoring will keep them anchored.

Actions now speak louder than words. The Fed’s actions are telling us loud and clear that at least so far they have been willing to step hard on what the believe is the inflation pedal to soften a slowdown, with unemployment still very near what they consider full-employment.

The question is: how sever does inflation have to get for the Fed to address it with action rather than ‘monitoring’?

Monetary policy

Now let me turn to monetary policy. The federal funds rate has been cut by 2¼ percentage points since September and now stands at 3 percent. With near-term expected inflation of just above 2 percent, the real—inflation adjusted—funds rate is around 1 percent or slightly lower, which represents an accommodative posture.

OK, they do consider the current FF rate accommodative.

And as core creeps up, the Fed sees it as more accommodative.

I believe that accommodation is appropriate because the financial shock and the housing cycle have significantly restrained economic growth.

But not inflation, at least not yet.

While growth seems likely to be sluggish this year, the Fed’s policy actions should help to promote a pickup in growth over time. I consider it most probable that the U.S. economy will experience slow growth, and not outright recession, in coming quarters. At the same time, core consumer inflation seems likely to decline gradually to somewhat below 2 percent over the next couple of years, a level that is consistent with price stability.

Why is it likely to decline? Don’t see any support for what that position apart from it used to decline when unemployment went up. But even then, it took a lot more unemployment to decline the way they are expecting it to.

However, economic prospects are unusually uncertain. And downside risks to economic growth remain.

And that means a downside risk to inflation as they must be assuming inflation is a function of growth? If so, why not say it?

This implies that, going forward, the Committee must carefully monitor and assess the effects of ongoing financial and economic developments on the outlook and be prepared to act in a timely manner to address developments that alter the forecast or the risks to it.

My guess is the Fed’s forecast has not been revised down since the last meeting, but the inflation forecast may be revised up and appropriate monetary policy might be implying higher rates down the road.

I expect she would vote for a rate cut at the next meeting if conditions remain the same, if she was still a voting member.

Now, I’d be glad to take your questions.

Endnotes

In recent months, and particularly toward year-end, strains were evident in the term interbank funding markets; in these markets, banks borrow from and lend to each other, with loans maturing in a number of weeks, months, or even a year. The problem has been that banks that would normally lend their excess funds to other banks that need them became reluctant to do so. This may reflect banks’ recognition of the need to preserve liquidity to meet unexpected credit demands, greater uncertainty about the creditworthiness of counterparties and concerns relating to capital positions, on top of typical, year-end balance sheet considerations. A heightened focus on liquidity is logical when the markets for securitized assets held by banks have become highly illiquid and when the potential exists for some customers—such as struggling mortgage companies and others—to draw on unsecured credit lines. These markets have improved since the end of last year, perhaps in part because of the Fed’s introduction of the Term Auction Facility, which gives banks another route besides the discount window to tap into the Fed’s lending function. (Banks had not used the discount window very much despite their need for liquidity because they were concerned that doing so might erroneously signal to other financial institutions that they were in bad straits. The plan for the TFA, which the Fed created in cooperation with the European Central Bank and the National Bank of Switzerland, was announced on December 12.)


Government spending may be accelerating

US Jan budget surplus narrows as spending hits record

by David Lawder

WASHINGTON, Feb 12 (Reuters) – The U.S. government posted a $17.84 billion budget surplus for January, less than half the year-earlier surplus, as spending hit a record for the month while receipts fell from a year ago, the U.S. Treasury said on Tuesday.

The January surplus narrowed compared to a year-earlier surplus of $38.24 billion and also missed the $23.5 billion surplus forecast by economists polled by Reuters.

A Treasury spokeswoman said January is more often a deficit-producing month, with January deficits in 34 of the past 53 years.

Federal outlays last month grew to $237.38 billion — a record for the month of January — from $222.37 billion in January 2007.

Might be back on the 7% growth trend as 2007 spending my have been delayed and moved forward to 2008.

But after years of consistently strong year-on-year growth, government tax receipts dipped to $255.22 billion in January from $260.61 billion from the same month a year earlier.

Could be a sign of economic weakness.

I don’t have the details yet – there can be a lot more to these numbers than the headlines indicate.

Economic data has shown a substantial slowing of the U.S. economy in recent weeks, including a decline of 17,000 non-farm jobs in January. The White House has forecast that the full-year budget deficit will more than double to $410 billion this year due to the revenue slowdown and a $152 billion in fiscal stimulus spending package.

Now a $169 billion package.

The deficit for the first four months of fiscal 2008, which began Oct. 1, widened to $87.70 billion, from a $42.17 billion budget gap for the same period a year earlier. (Reporting by David Lawder; editing by Gary Crosse)

Government spending and exports now supporting GDP and offsetting some of the consumer weakness.


♥

Oil AND interest rates up?

It’s only been a few hours, but seems the first time since August higher oil doesn’t mean lower interest rates, and might even mean higher rates.

Up until now, higher oil prices meant a weaker economy and therefore Fed rate cuts.

I’ve been watching for a shift to higher oil prices meaning higher inflation and therefore Fed rate hikes.

Recent developments- Yellen (the biggest Fed dove) says core inflation is above her comfort zone, and that energy prices are finding their way into core inflation.

Why did she volunteer that when no one was asking? Signalling?

Why not just repeat something like ‘inflation expectations remain well contained but we remain vigilant…’ as before?

Plosser, Fisher, Lasker said much the same, but they are the hawks. It’s not news when they say it.

Maybe they all got an update from the Fed’s economics staff?

Might be revising q2,3, and 4 upwards due to the fiscal package?

They had already expected a second half return to ‘trend’ due to their interest rate cuts.

So let’s guess at what might conservatively be the current mid points of the Fed’s forecast with the new fiscal package-

0% q1, 1% q2, 2.5% q3, 3% q4?

Here’s the problem. The mainstream belief is that inflation is a function of the output gap.

If inflation is too high- above your comfort zone- you bring it down by engineering a sufficient output gap.

That means it takes a weaker economy with higher unemployment to bring down core inflation.

The first step is to try to estimate the GDP ‘speed limit’ which is the max growth rate with inflation staying within Fed comfort zones.

Well, the Q4 data point was .6% gdp growth and inflation above comfort zones. Forward looking Q1 data points are 0 growth with inflation above comfort zones and rising. Q2, Q3 and Q4 now show increasing growth which means at best inflation won’t be projected to fall, and probably continue to deteriorate.

So what is the best guess for the max GDP growth rate consistent with inflation within FOMC member comfort zones?

The hawks said slower growth might not bring down inflation. The dove said she expects slower growth to bring down inflation.

But the forecasts are now for increasing rates of growth, and current conditions are already driving up prices past the Fed’s comfort zones.

Also, the Fed forecasts for 2 years forward always presume about a 2% inflation rate.

That’s because the forecast assumes ‘appropriate monetary policy’ to meet the Fed’s objectives.

The Fed’s interest rate forecast is not released with the rest of the forecast. Built into that model’s forecast is the staff’s calculation of ‘appropriate monetary policy.’

Seems to me that with growth revised up and inflation persisting even with weak q4 and weak q1 growth the model’s ‘appropriate monetary policy’ would be expected to include sufficient rate hikes to be consistent with the 2% inflation rate 2 years down the road.

Recap-

The only way the Fed knows to bring inflation down is to manage the output gap.

You don’t wait for the economy to get strong (achieve a 0 output gap) and then hike rates. That just makes it worse and more costly to keep an appropriate monetary policy/output gap to bring inflation down.

You have to not let the output gap too close to 0.

The Fed has always known this, but since August has feared a deflationary collapse due to supply side issues in the financial sector.

The recent past and the Fed’s forecast shows that instead of the feared deflation, inflation has now climbed above their comfort zones and appears to be persisting. And even looking higher, even with near 0 growth.

And last week’s Fed speeches raised concerns about the possibility that slowing growth has not and may not bring down inflation as anticipated.

And even Yellen volunteered that energy prices are beginning to elevate core inflation measures, and inflation expectations are showing signs of moving up.

Yes, the economy is weak. Yes, there are downside risks. But the economy is strong enough to be relentlessly pushing up prices, including core, and now the forecasts for growth have all been revised up due to the fiscal package.

If the FOMC shifts from fear of a deflationary collapse to fear of a moderate recession with prices holding firm, rate cuts are no longer appropriate monetary policy.


♥