Excellent post on the MMT controversy

Straw Men (And Women)

By Peter Cooper

This post is for all the MMT foot soldiers out there in cyberspace, including myself and most readers (prominent MMT economists who are kind enough to drop in from time to time excepted, of course).

Come on, we know who we are. Battling it out in diverse message forums, matching wits with fellow participants who, judging from their arguments, mostly appear to read our posts with their eyes shut and their fingers in their ears to block out the sounds of our linked video presentations. This navel-gazing exercise may seem self-indulgent to the crustier MMT old-timers among us, but, hey, rationalize it, we deserve it!

The post is also for readers who have not yet made up their minds about MMT. Think of this as a small taste of the kind of self-congratulatory back slapping you too will be able to enjoy at heteconomist if you decide to join the ranks of the foot soldiers. Enjoy! You also deserve it!

Straw Men in Cyberspace

On a private message forum I often visit, a regular participant – who is very bright, and a good contributor on many topics – recently posted a criticism of the MMT position on budget deficits that went something like this:

Budget deficits increase demand in some areas and decrease it in others. To illustrate the point I will show an extreme example. Say Honest Annie has $10,000 in savings. Mr Lucky is given $100,000,000 to stimulate the economy. Oh look, now Annie can produce more goods because Mr Lucky can afford to buy them. Of course, look at poor Annie’s real disposition. This new demand comes with the devaluation of her hard-earned savings. What is changing is that now she has to produce more to be able to afford more goods. The government has tricked her into having to work more because her savings have been devalued due to inflation. Sure, Mr Lucky is happy because Annie is producing more goods for him, but there are two sides to the coin.

Clearly the government should not adopt such a ridiculous policy in which it randomly gives one person $100 million in an economy where a typical person has savings of $10,000. But even in terms of the ludicrous example, the poster’s logic is lacking.

If Mr Lucky spent some of the money to buy stuff from Honest Annie, and she had the available time and resources to respond to the additional demand at current prices, she would receive some of Mr Lucky’s money in payment and also have increased spending power to purchase output from Mr Lucky or somebody else. The deficit expenditure can increase demand in some areas without reducing it in others provided the economy is operating below full capacity.

The question is whether there are idle resources that people would willingly put to use if there was demand for the resulting output, and whether this additional output could be supplied in a non-inflationary manner.

No one in the MMT camp is suggesting the government should net spend more than is necessary to enable the purchase of potential output at current prices.

The author of the example is influenced by the Austrian school, so some of his reasoning is defensible within that framework. In particular, as I discussed here and here, the Austrian definition of inflation is different from the one used by other economists. For everyone but the Austrians, inflation means a persistent rise in the general price level (the weighted average of all prices of final goods and services), not an expansion of broader money per se.

This can lead to differences between Austrians and non-Austrians in their assessments of whether inflation is occurring. If there is a rise in general prices, there will typically be an expansion of broader money to accommodate it unless real potential output shrinks due to a supply shock. In this case, both Austrians and non-Austrians alike will observe inflation. But it is possible for the broader money supply to expand (inflation for Austrians) without general prices rising (no inflation for other economists) whenever the economy is operating below full capacity. This means that from the Austrian perspective, it makes sense to suggest deficit expenditure will reduce the value of money even if, for other economists, there is no inflation.

Differences such as this can be discussed as part of a healthy debate. What is more annoying is the practice of creating straw-man arguments, such as the suggestion that MMT economists are advocating mindless spending out of all proportion to the actual demand deficiency or without any thought to the allocation of that net spending. The tactic often appears to be deliberate, in that there is a wilful misinterpretation of the argument to make it easier to ridicule or criticize. No matter how many times the point is clarified, the wilful (and convenient) misinterpretation will be repeated as if nothing has changed. The result is a discussion that fails to advance beyond irrelevant mischaracterizations and attempts to set (reset) the record straight.

As a practical matter for foot soldiers, we need to balance the need to deal with such mischaracterizations with the desire to develop the argument further for those not thrown by the mischaracterizations or to present the same argument elsewhere. At some point, it is probably best to assume that intelligent readers have been provided with enough clarification to make up their own minds about the merits of the straw-man argument, and just get on with advancing the discussion, or if the point has been made, move on to other forums. There is no need to convince every person in every forum.

MMT – and heterodox approaches, in general – seem more susceptible to this kind of straw-man treatment because its proponents have to make the running. In debates with critics or skeptics, the aim of the MMT proponent is usually to explain why the current dominant understanding of the economy is lacking, and why an alternative may offer an improvement in understanding.

A skeptic who is only interested in a better understanding of the economy has no motive to mischaracterize MMT arguments. The motive for engaging in discussion for such a person would be to understand the approach to enable an informed assessment of it. But when a skeptic or critic is more interested in defending a preconceived view of the world – possibly for psychological, political, or careerist reasons – their motive may not be to understand but to obfuscate, sidetrack, or otherwise hold up the discussion in ways that at least muddies the waters enough to make it difficult for others, who may be trying to understand without prejudging positions, to separate nonsense from valid argument, especially if they do not have a training in economics.

Consider journalists who write on economic matters, for example. In a way, it is hard to blame them for erring on the side of the orthodoxy when in doubt if they don’t have sufficient confidence in their own understanding of the subject. When in doubt, it is surely safer to go with the view of a Nobel Prize recipient or Professor from an Ivy League university over the views of a heterodox economist, even if the heterodox position seems to make more sense.

Opponents of the heterodox position can take advantage of this, knowing that they do not have to win arguments, or even engage in them in many cases, provided there is sufficient doubt over the heterodox position, whether because of perception, status, obfuscation or deliberately disruptive tactics, which on the internet can of course be done anonymously.

Straw Men in Academia

Straw-man argumentation is not limited to the orthodoxy or the internet. Heterodox schools use this tactic in disputes among themselves. For example, Marx’s theory of value was widely claimed to be “internally inconsistent” for eighty years on the basis of a straw man (the dominant dual-system, simultaneist interpretation of his theory) before a group of economists were finally able to demonstrate that Marx’s work could be interpreted in a way that not only gave it internal coherence but reproduced all of his results on value, including the long-run tendency of the rate of profit to fall, which had supposedly been “disproved” by Okishio’s theorem.

It wasn’t until the 1980s that papers began to be published by economists adhering to the so-called “temporal single-system interpretation” of Marx, demonstrating the theoretical coherence – validity, not necessarily correctness – of his theory of value when interpreted in a temporal and “single-system” way. It took another twenty-five years of persistence by these economists before Sraffians (who were the most prominent antagonists) and other critics grudgingly stopped dismissing Marx’s theory in pat phrases repeated over and over again without any authority other than the insinuation of authority.

One of the leading protagonists in this debate, Andrew Kliman, has written an accessible book for the generalist reader documenting the history of the debate and summarizing the major findings. For anyone interested in the debate over Marx’s theory of value, it is well worth reading, and eye-opening in bringing to light the extent of intellectual dishonesty in academia, including within the heterodoxy.

The straw-man tactic of the Sraffians served to discredit Marx and help to create a justification for alternative theories (e.g. Sraffianism) to replace or “correct” Marx’s theory. The tactic was also employed by developers of an array of alternative, though short-lived, value theories, such as the New Interpretation, Simultaneous Single-System Interpretation, Value Form theory, etc. A certain career benefit and “respectability” no doubt also comes from distancing oneself from Marx’s theory of value in a capitalist society.

The straw-man attack on Marx’s theory was effective partly because Marxism is outside the orthodoxy and Marxists have little to no presence in academic economics, let alone clout. Another reason for its effectiveness may be that Marxist thought is critical of the capitalist system itself. It is not merely reformist. This is not exactly the most career-savvy research program for an up-and-coming academic.

None of this is to suggest that Sraffianism or any of the other alternative theories are not valid approaches in their own right. It is simply to insist that the developers of these theories were not entitled to assert the invalidity of Marx’s theory almost like a religious mantra when the argument relied on a straw man.

The unjustified but highly successful eighty-year banishment of Marx’s theory can be contrasted with the lack of impact the Cambridge Capital Controversy has had on the dominance of neoclassical economics. This time the position of the Sraffians in theoretical terms was very strong, and their central points were conceded by Paul Samuelson and other leading neoclassical participants in the debate, yet the victory has so far had little impact on the status quo in academic economics.

The strategically effective response of the neoclassical orthodoxy to heterodox critiques drawing on the results of the Cambridge Capital Controversy has been simply not to respond through debate but rather ignore the implications, stop publishing heterodox work in the top journals, and cease hiring heterodox economists in the most prestigious universities or leading policymaking institutions (see Nobel-nomics for a polemical take on the aftermath of the Capital Debates).

When aimed at the orthodoxy, even legitimate criticism struggles to make a dent. For the heterodoxy, the very strongest arguments take a long time to break through.

Eventually, though, as MMT commentator rvm often reminds me, truth will out. Advances in understanding in many areas of human endeavor have faced the same kind of opposition throughout history. Even now, some heterodox advances in economics eventually slip in through the back door of neoclassical economics.

For example, there appears to be an increasing recognition among monetary researchers that some traditional concepts are untenable. Recent notable examples apply to the money-multiplier theory and money endogeneity. Understanding of these points has been well established in Post Keynesian economics for a long time. Now, slowly, some of the ideas are creeping in to mainstream analysis (usually without appropriate credit being given to earlier heterodox work).

All this is a longwinded way of saying that the road is uphill, but the only option is to keep plugging away. Some of the leading proponents of MMT have been grinding away for thirty years now. As internet foot soldiers, we can follow their lead. Sooner or later, perhaps long after we’re all dead, society will wake up to reality, strengthen conceptual understanding, and implement sensible policies.

Ancient historians of twentieth and twenty-first century economic thought will look back and realize that much of the truth was worked out by Kalecki, Keynes, Lerner, CofFEE, UMKC, TCOTU, etc. From their vantage point of 5000 AED (five thousand years After Environmental Destruction), orthodox historians will wonder how the clear and cogent answers of MMT could possibly have been ignored by so many experts of the era, who seemed inexplicably fond of straw men. These orthodox thinkers of the future will know with utter certainty that they could never be so close-minded!

A Comment on MMT Internet Discussions

There is one particular straw man that is repeatedly erected by critics of MMT. I’m sure most foot soldiers reading this will have noticed it. It is one that I find especially grating. The best (i.e. most irritating) phrase I’ve seen to encapsulate the nuances of this particular straw man is the refrain:

MMT claims we can print prosperity.

The phrase “print prosperity” is shorthand for the common message board accusation that MMT ignores real resources and gets bamboozled by money as if it is magic. The accusation is very common. The term “print prosperity” was coined, to the best of my knowledge, by a Math Professor, no less, who happens to be keen on the kind of “fiscal conservatism” advocated by the Concord Coalition.

I consider it a perverse injustice that, in online discussions, MMT sympathizers are frequently reproached for imagining that “we can print prosperity” when in fact it is us who constantly stress as a fundamental point that the only true constraints are resource based, not financial or monetary in nature. We are the ones insisting that if we have the resources, we can put them to use. It is the neoclassical orthodoxy and others who try to make out that we can’t use resources, even if they are available, because of some magical, mysterious monetary or financial constraint. Just who is it that believes in magic here?

MMT shows clearly that if we have the resources, money is no obstacle to a government that issues its own flexible exchange-rate fiat currency. It is not saying that creating money magically creates goods and services. It is saying that it is nonsense – superstitious nonsense – to think affordability for such a government could be about money rather than resources.

Obviously, anyone is entitled to disagree with the MMT position. But they are not entitled purposefully to misrepresent MMT as suggesting that it is oblivious to real resource constraints when it is alternative theories that attempt to obfuscate matters by conjuring up fictitious “financial constraints” (e.g. the neoclassical “government budget constraint” framework).

Take the debate over how to address the aging population for example. It should be obvious – and is obvious in MMT – that the only way to address this issue is to increase future productive capacity. This involves the application of real resources now to research, infrastructure development, education (including in areas relevant to servicing an aging population), etc.

Clearly, MMT is not, as many internet critics claim, saying that creating money solves the problem. It is really the MMT critics who are falling into the trap of thinking money rather than the application of real resources is the solution, despite their frequent protestations to the contrary. They are the ones who think that if the government “saves” money now, this will somehow help to address the needs of the aging population in, let’s say, twenty years time.

Yet, these same people also stress that you can’t “print prosperity”. Well, if you can’t “print prosperity” – and we all agree on that – what good is that money the government supposedly should stash away going to be twenty years from now? It won’t help to provide the infrastructure and technological knowledge that was not developed in the preceding twenty years because governments preferred to “save” money for the future rather than apply resources to the real task of raising productive capacity.

Oh well. We shrug and move on. Such are the trials and tribulations of an internet foot soldier.

Bernanke text

Just when you think he’s making progress:

>   
>   (email exchange)
>   
>   On Thu, Feb 3, 2011 at 1:41 PM, Cullen wrote:
>   
>   After a glimpse of hope from some of Bernanke’s speeches late last year
>   he appears to have suffered some sort of memory loss as he is once again
>   talking about the dangers of the govt debt:
>   

Bernanke:

By definition, the unsustainable trajectories of deficits and debt that the CBO outlines cannot actually happen, because creditors would never be willing to lend to a government with debt, relative to national income, that is rising without limit.

Link to text

Comments on Non-Mfg ISM

Looks from the chart we’re getting close to the post Bush tax cut, coming out of that recession highs, so we’re on track for our 3-5% read gdp growth guestimates.

And the high productivity reported today reinforces our thoughts on unemployment coming down only slowly as well.

Last time around the expansion phase of what became the sub prime crisis was a substantial contributor to private sector credit growth. Without that kind of contribution from somewhere else, this recovery could be more modest than the last.

For exports to be sustained, the govt would have to keep the dollar down with fx purchases and reserve building, which in my humble opinion isn’t going to happen. That means the adjustment takes place via a climbing US dollar that continues until it dampens exports. Much like what the euro zone has experienced for the last decade or so.


Karim writes:

Multi-year highs for overall index, new orders (3rd highest on record-chart attached), and employment.
Anecdotes also very positive.

  • “New initiatives creating increase in spending.” (Finance & Insurance)
  • “Indications are that business is picking up and that 2011 could see positive growth across many industries. We are seeing an increase in orders at the beginning of the year.” (Professional, Scientific & Technical Services)
  • “Starting to see higher prices in many areas. Low inventory levels are leading to longer delivery time frames.” (Public Administration)
  • “Business uncertainty seems to be subsiding.” (Management of Companies & Support Services)
  • “Business activity is picking up. The challenges in the textile market (cotton/polyester) are significantly impacting price along with the inability to secure pricing for a period longer than two months.” (Accommodation & Food Services)
  • “2011 looking better than 2010.” (Information)



Jan Dec
Composite 59.4 57.1
Business activity 64.6 62.9
Prices Paid 72.1 69.5
New Orders 64.9 61.4
Backlog of Orders 50.5 48.5
Supplier Deliveries 53.5 51.5
Inventory Change 49.0 52.5
Inventory Sentiment 60.0 61.5
Employment 54.5 52.6
Export orders 53.5 56.0
Imports 53.5 51.0

Refining Concerns Overshadow Higher Shell Profit

It’s an agonizingly slow process, but it is starting to feel like the world is turning away from crude oil consumption.

The Saudis are the swing producer, and can set price at any level they wish.
But if they set the price ‘too high’ over time demand shifts away from them due to both conservation and substitution.
(And if they set the price too low, consumption rises to eventually use up their excess capacity.)

It’s feeling to me like they have the price high enough to both cool consumption through both conservation and substitution, as evidenced by the demand for refined products discussed below and charts I’ve posted previously.

And slowly but surely the price of crude- as well as the unattractiveness of being dependent on it and the negative connotations of burning fossil fuels in general- is driving the investment and technology for both better fuel economy and a long term switch to electric power for transportation, as well as for a shift away from fossil fuels in general.

In theory a monopolist like the Saudis might respond by dropping the price to a level that discourages/crushes the investments associated with the switch out of crude- maybe $40 per barrel. But there’s no sign of that yet, and they may not want to dip into their cash reserves to the extent needed to support a move like that.

Nor, alternatively, with what’s going on in the region, might they believe then can afford politically to apply that much austerity to their population.

Also, this is all fundamentally $US friendly, and works to offset the negative impact on the dollar from higher crude prices per se.

Refining Concerns Overshadow Higher Shell Profit

By Sarah Young

February 3 (Bloomberg) — Shell disappointed investors on Thursday with below-forecast fourth-quarter profit, with concerns over its refining business overshadowing a sharp rise driven by higher oil prices.

The results followed strong earnings from Chevron and Exxon Mobil, although BP, struggling to put the Gulf of Mexico oil spill behind it, fared less well.

Shell shares fell 3 percent, with analysts saying they had expected more and expressing concern over continued weakness in the Anglo-Dutch oil major’s refining business, with oil product sales rising just 5 percent year-on-year.

“Our earnings were impacted by weak refining margins, pressure on certain regional natural gas prices, and volatility in downstream marketing margins as a result of rising oil prices,” Shell said.

Arbuthnot analyst Dougie Youngson said margins would be under increased pressure if oil prices remained at around $100 a barrel for long.

Benchmark U.S. crude prices averaged about $85 per barrel in the fourth quarter, up from $76 in the fourth quarter of 2009, but have since risen to above the $100 mark.

“The global market continues to see weak demand and pricing for oil products,” Youngson said in a note.

Shell said that despite a year-on-year improvement its refining results were lower compared with the third quarter because of “increased downtime at major refining facilities.”

Shell’s earnings on a current cost of supplies (CCS) basis, jumped to $5.7 billion from $1.2 billion a year ago when it suffered heavy refining losses. But Jos Versteeg, an analyst at Theodoor Glissen, said this was still less than anticipated.
Excluding non-operating and one-off items the fourth quarter result was $4.1 billion, short of a forecast for $4.85 billion, according to a Reuters poll.

Analysts welcomed Shell’s announcement of a $0.42 dividend for the quarter and the fact it expected to maintain that level for the first quarter of 2011.

Shell’s planned capital investment of $25-$27 billion for 2011 was also well received, with Sanford Bernstein’s Oswald Clint saying capex appeared under control.

However, Arbuthnot’s Youngson said he was concerned about Shell’s focus on gas, given continued price weakness and oversupply forecasts.

U.K. Service Industries Return to ‘Pre-Snow’ Growth

Still looks to me like the govt deficit is plenty high enough to support at least modest gdp growth until the pro active austerity measures actually reduce it.

UK Headlines:

U.K. Service Industries Return to ‘Pre-Snow’ Growth

Inflation Could Force Bank of England to Raise Interest Rates, Says Deputy Governor Charlie Bean

UK Faces US-style Jobless Recovery, Says Institute for Fiscal Studies

Wealthy Britons Planning to Increase Spending in 2011, HSBC Says

Brussels May Punish German Competitiveness, Die Zeit Reports

And stupider.

Maybe the world should outlaw lawnmowers and require lawns be cut with toenail clippers to create jobs. I’d suggest they were trying to weaken the euro but surely that would be giving them too much credit…

Brussels May Punish German Competitiveness, Die Zeit Reports

By Jeff Black

February 2 (Bloomberg) — European Union officials are considering measures that would punish countries that run excessive trade surpluses or whose competitiveness is too high, Germany’s Die Zeit newspaper reported, citing a document.

The proposed measures, outlined in a position paper obtained by the newspaper, would require states to keep their current account balance within a “corridor” of plus or minus four percent of gross domestic product, Die Zeit said.

A similar boundary would apply for the yearly change in unit labor costs, a measure of price competitiveness, the newspaper said. In 2008, Germany’s current account surplus was 7 percent of GDP and its price competitiveness improved by 5.5 percent, Die Zeit reported.

ISM- Obama boom!


Karim writes:

Across the board strength. More evidence that the inventory drag in Q4 was involuntary (demand running well ahead of production). While some of these figures may cool, the order backlog and supplier delivery indices (lead times) suggest very strong data for the next few quarters.

  • Overall index: Highest since May 2004
  • New orders: Highest since Dec 2003
  • Employment index highest since April 1973
  • Export orders: Highest since Dec 1988



ISM Jan Dec
Index 60.8 58.5
Prices paid 81.5 72.5
Production 63.5 63.0
New Orders 67.8 62.0
Backlog of orders 58.0 47.0
Supplier deliveries 58.6 56.7
Inventories 52.4 51.8
Customer inventories 45.5 40.0
Employment 61.7 58.9
Export Orders 62.0 54.5
Imports 55.0 50.5

Yes, manufacturing is being led by exports, which tells me to watch for a dollar rally.

The problem is crude is moving higher, but that may be temporary and fall back as the Egyptian crisis gets resolved, if the Saudis don’t support the higher prices. And the US cost advantage with the dollar at current levels could drive the dollar higher even with the higher crude prices.

The federal budget deficit remains plenty high to support the 3-5% reported real growth, which is enough to bring unemployment down some as well with productivity running maybe 2.5% or so, but unemployment probably won’t fall fast enough for the Fed to declare victory anytime soon. And with core inflation numbers still decelerating the Fed continues to see itself ‘failing’ on both mandates as Chairman Bernanke reported in his last address.

For the Fed, the GDP growth limit is as high as possible without jeopardizing price stability. While they have calculated that should be around the 3-4% real growth level, if the evidence supports higher rates of gdp growth with price stability they should in theory have no problem with higher levels of real growth.

Risks remain China, Europe, and US fiscal tightening, as well as a sharp spike in crude prices

EU Daily | Europe Manufacturing Growth Quickens to 9-Month High

As previously discussed, it doesn’t get any better than this from a German point of view.

And it could be several more months or quarters before the austerity hits them.

EU Headlines

Europe Manufacturing Growth Quickens to 9-Month High

Europe Unemployment Remains Near Highest in More Than 12 Years

ECB pauses bond purchases as crisis eases

German January Unemployment Falls to 18-Year Low

France Won’t Lift Sales Tax Rate Right Now, Lagarde Says

Spanish Bank Tackles Toxic Assets

Italian Unemployment Rate Holds Near 7-Year High in December

Central Bank cuts Ireland’s outlook over austerity

Greece confident over new rescue loan installment

Industry warns Europe on competitiveness

Spain’s Salgado Says EU Rescue Fund Should Be More Flexible

Tevatron Is Shutting Down

>   
>   (email exchange)
>   
>   On Tue, Feb 1, 2011 at 2:30 AM, Roger wrote:
>   
>   This is sad & pathetic
>   

Agreed.

It’s being shut down for the wrong reason.

Add all this to ever growing real cost of not understanding the monetary system.

The Tevatron Is Shutting Down And You Know What That Means

By Courtney Comstock

January 31 (Business Insider) — The Tevatron, the particle collider that has been smashing together subatomic particles in Illinois since 1983, will be shut down by late 2011.

The Large Hadron Collider in Geneva does the same thing, only 7 times faster, and so the Tevaton has lost funding ($50 million per year) from the Department of Energy, according to the New York Times.

It’s sad for everyone except Wall Street.

For everyone else it means:

  • We’re losing some of our science edge to Europe
  • 1,200 physicists are out of a job
  • Particle physics might not be advanced as soon as everyone hoped
  • We might be at least one step further away from understanding the big stuff, like how the world works

For Wall Street it means that 1,200 physicists, aka potential quant material, are available for hire.

And as someone pointed out in a letter to the editor, Wall Street loves hiring quants!

China Central Bank says Fed easing ineffective, dangerous

I suspect they know better but continue to play us for the fools we have proven to be.

Fortunately they want to net export…

China c.bank says Fed easing ineffective, dangerous

January 30 (IBTimes) — Quantitative easing by the Federal Reserve and other central banks cannot address fundamental economic problems but may lead to excessive global liquidity and competitive currency depreciation,China’s central bank said on Sunday.

In its monetary policy report for the final quarter of 2010, the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) also confirmed that it would target 16 percent growth of the broad M2 measure of money supply this year, down from the 19.9 pct growth recorded at the end of 2010.

The central bank said the Fed’s monetary easing was pushing up international commodity prices and asset prices in emerging markets, including China.

“Quantitative easing policy cannot fundamentally address economic problems, and it may cause excessive liquidity on a global scale as well as risks of competitive currency depreciation,” the Chinese central bank said in its 59-page report.

“It is creating imported inflation and short-term capital inflows, pressuring emerging markets,” it said.

As a result, China needed to work hard to soak up liquidity from foreign exchange inflows in order to minimize the impact on the domestic economy, it added.

The central bank reiterated that it would keep the yuan CNY=CFXS basically stable while making the exchange rate regime more flexible.

The central bank said it would continue to use different tools, including interest rates, bank reserve requirements and open-market operations, to rein in money supply and bank credit growth as a way of handling inflationary pressure.